Top-Rated Free Essay
Preview

The U.S. Deficit/Debt Problem: a Longer-Run Perspective

Good Essays
5693 Words
Grammar
Grammar
Plagiarism
Plagiarism
Writing
Writing
Score
Score
The U.S. Deficit/Debt Problem: a Longer-Run Perspective
The U.S. Deficit/Debt Problem:
A Longer-Run Perspective
Daniel L. Thornton

The U.S. national debt now exceeds 100 percent of gross domestic product. Given that a significant amount of this debt is the result of governmental efforts to mitigate the effects of the financial crisis, the recession, and the anemic recovery, it is tempting to think that the debt problem is a recent phenomenon.
This article shows that the United States was on a collision course with a major debt problem for nearly four decades before the financial crisis. In particular, the debt problem began around 1970 when the government decided to significantly increase spending without a corresponding increase in revenue. The analysis suggests that the debt problem cannot be permanently resolved without creating a mechanism to prevent the government from running persistent deficits in the future. (JEL E62, H62, H63)
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, November/December 2012, 94(6), pp. 441-55.

he U.S. debt has surpassed 100 percent of gross domestic product (GDP). This debt burden is due in part to the extremely large deficits incurred by attempts to mitigate the effects of the financial crisis, the relatively deep and prolonged recession, and the anemic economic recovery. Given the emphasis on the financial crisis and its aftermath, it is important to realize the U.S. deficit/debt problem began over four decades ago. This longerrun perspective suggests that the recognition of the seriousness of the problem and the need for fundamental change eventually would have occurred. The recent financial crisis merely brought the U.S. deficit/debt problem to the public’s attention sooner rather than later. The analysis here shows that the U.S. deficit/debt problem began during the early 1970s when the government started to increase spending significantly without a corresponding increase in tax revenue. This article also analyzes various aspects of government revenues and expenditures to better understand the different elements of the debate on preventing the U.S. deficit/debt problem from becoming the U.S. deficit/debt crisis.1

T

Daniel L. Thornton is a vice president and economic adviser at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The author thanks Clemens Kool for helpful comments.
© 2012, The Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. The views expressed in this article are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Federal Reserve System, the Board of Governors, or the regional Federal Reserve Banks. Articles may be reprinted, reproduced, published, distributed, displayed, and transmitted in their entirety if copyright notice, author name(s), and full citation are included. Abstracts, synopses, and other derivative works may be made only with prior written permission of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

441

Thornton

Figure 1
The Federal Surplus/Deficit as a Percent of GNP/GDP
Percent
10

1800 to 1990 = GNP
1991 to 2020 = GDP

5
0
–5

War of 1812

–10
–15
Civil War
–20
–25

WWI

Actual
2011 Projection
2000 Projection

–30
1800

1820

1840

WWII
1860

1880

1900

1920

1940

1960

1980

2000

2020

NOTE: GNP, gross national product.
SOURCE: The baseline budget projections to 2020 are from the Congressional Budget Office.

THE U.S. DEFICIT/DEBT PROBLEM: WHEN DID IT BEGIN?
A long-run perspective on U.S. government deficits is helpful in understanding the current deficit/debt problem. Figure 1 shows the history of U.S. budget surpluses/deficits from 1800 through 2011 and Congressional Budget Office baseline budget projections up to 2020. Three aspects of this figure are noteworthy. First, until the recent financial crisis, large deficits have been associated with great wars—the War of 1812, the Civil War, and World Wars I and II. The only large peacetime deficit occurred in 1933 during the Great Depression, when the deficit hit a peak of 6.6 percent of GDP. In contrast, the deficits for 2009, 2010, and 2011 have all exceeded
8.7 percent.
Second, each large deficit was followed by a period of budget surpluses or very small deficits.
Indeed, with the exception of major wars and the Great Depression, the deficit relative to GDP averaged essentially zero.
Third, a marked change in the behavior of the deficit occurred circa 1970. For the decade preceding 1970, the United States also had fairly persistent deficits, but they were relatively small—on average, 0.8 percent of GDP. In contrast, the deficit averaged 2.1 percent for the 1970s,
3.9 percent for the 1980s, 2.2 percent for the 1990s, and 3.0 percent for the 2000s. Over the entire
1970-2010 period the deficit averaged 2.8 percent of GDP.
The effects of the wartime deficits and peacetime surpluses are reflected in the size of the debt relative to GDP. Figure 2 shows the federal debt as a percent of GDP since 1840. The debt rose dramatically relative to GDP during the Civil War but declined more or less continuously
442

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

Thornton

Figure 2
Gross Government Debt as a Percent of GDP
Percent
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
1840 1850 1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

SOURCE: Historical Statistics of the United States, Office of Management and Budget, and Haver Analytics.

until the United States entered WWI, when the percentage again peaked at the Civil War level.
The percentage again declined until the Great Depression and WWII, when it rose dramatically to a peak of 121 percent in 1946. After WWII the deficit as a percent of GDP declined nearly monotonically before leveling out around 1970. Because the deficit grew faster than GDP on average over the 1970-2007 period, the percent of GDP increased from 36 percent in 1970 to 64 percent in 2007, the highest peacetime level in U.S. history. Since 2007, the debt has increased to more than 100 percent of GDP.
The large and persistent deficits over the 38 years preceding the financial crisis suggest that the United States would have had a serious deficit/debt problem without the financial crisis and recession. A back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests that had the United States continued on the path it was on, the country would have achieved a debt-to-GDP ratio of 100 percent around
2017. The recent events merely forced the recognition of the reality of the situation sooner rather than later. Indeed, several economists and market analysts issued warnings of an impending debt crisis (see Gokhale and Smetters, 2003; Kotlikoff and Burns, 2012; and references therein).
The conclusion that the United States was on a collision course with a debt problem is supported by a simple analysis of government revenues and expenditures as a percent of GDP.2
Figure 3 presents government spending and revenue as a percent of GDP from 1950 through
2010. The black and blue dashed lines denote the average federal government revenue and expenditures, respectively, as a percent of GDP from 1950 through 1969. The figure shows that after 1970 both revenues and expenditures increased on average relative to the previous two decades; however, revenue increased marginally, while expenditures increased significantly.
Revenue averaged 18.2 percent of GDP for the 1970-2007 period compared with 17.5 percent
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

443

Thornton

Figure 3
Revenue and Expenditures as a Percent of GDP (1950-2010)
Percent
30

25

20

15

10

Revenue/GDP
Expenditures/GDP
Average Revenue (1950-69)

5

Average Expenditures (1950-69)
0
1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

for the 1950-69 period, while expenditures averaged 20.6 percent and 18.1 percent, respectively, for the same two periods. On average, the government spent 2.4 percent of GDP more than it received in revenue during the 38-year period.
Figure 3 shows, however, that tax revenue as a percent of GDP increased from 17.5 percent of GDP to 20.6 percent of GDP from 1993 to 2000. This increase is associated with the tax increases introduced in 1993. Revenue subsequently decreased following passage of the Economic
Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA; a.k.a. the George W. Bush tax cuts).
The decline in tax revenue relative to GDP between 2000 and 2003 was likely due in part to the
2001 recession; 2007 tax revenue as a percent of GDP was at or above the 1950-69 average level during the 2006-08 period. The marked decline in revenue as a percent of GDP during the
2009-11 period is likely due to the financial crisis and the accompanying recession. Hence, while the Bush tax cuts may have been a contributing factor to the deficit after 2001, this analysis suggests that the average deficit from 1970 to 2007 was largely due to a marked increase in expenditures relative to GDP: The ratio of debt to GDP was 57 percent in 2000 and increased to only
64 percent by 2007. Hence, most of the increase in the debt over the entire 1970-2007 period occurred because the government spent much more than it collected in taxes—about $6 trillion more. Sources of Government Spending
What components of government spending account for the increase in spending during the
1970-2007 period? The answer to this question is shown in Figure 4, which shows federal spend444

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

Thornton

Figure 4
Federal Spending as a Percent of GDP by Categories (1950-2010)
Percent
16
Defense
IPD = Interest Paid on the Public Debt

14

SSM = Social Security and Medicare/Medicaid
OPI = Other Payments to Individuals
OFE = Other Federal Expenditures

12
10
8
6
4
2
0
1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

2005

2010

ing as a percent of GDP by categories from 1950 through 2010. The categories are defense spending (DS), interest paid on the public debt (IPD), Social Security and Medicare/Medicaid (SSM), other payments to individuals (OPI), and other federal expenditures (OFE). The figure shows that IPD and OFE have been relatively small and relatively constant over the period, with no discernible trend. Hence, the marked increase in spending cannot be due to IPD or OFE. It also appears that DS cannot account for the spending increase as it has generally trended down over the sample period ever since the late 1960s.
The figure shows that SSM and OPI are the main spending drivers over the 1970-2007 period.
These expenditures accounted for 5 percent of government spending as a percent of GDP in
1950 and had increased to only 6.1 percent of GDP by 1969. However, SSM and OPI spending as a percent of GDP doubled by 2007 to 12.1 percent of GDP. SSM and OPI spending increased by another 3.6 percentage points of GDP by 2010 to 15.7 percent of GDP.
The analysis above shows that OPI and SSM account for essentially all of the increase in government spending that has given rise to the deficit/debt problem. This section analyzes government spending in more detail to better pin down the source of the spending.
Figure 5 shows the percent of total federal spending annually from 1979 through 2011 by three categories: discretionary spending, mandatory spending, and interest payments on the national debt. Mandatory spending includes Social Security payments, Medicare, Medicaid, income security, other retirement and disability spending, and all other mandatory spending.
Income security includes unemployment compensation, Supplemental Security Income, the refundable portion of the earned income and child tax credits, supplemental nutrition assistance,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

445

Thornton

Figure 5
Government Spending by Categories
Percent
70

60

50

40

30
Discretionary
20

Mandatory
Interest

10

0
1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

family support, child nutrition, and foster care. The figure shows that the decline in discretionary spending as a percent of total government spending was essentially matched by an increase in mandatory spending. Discretionary spending decreased from 48 percent to 37 percent of total government spending between 1979 and 2011, while mandatory spending increased from 44 percent to 56 percent of total spending. Interest payments on the public debt increased from 8.5 percent to 15.5 percent of total spending between 1979 and 1997 but declined to just 6 percent of total spending in 2011. The decline in interest expense reflects the lower interest rates since
2000; this component of government spending is projected to grow significantly because of the marked increase in the size of the debt since the beginning of the financial crisis. Moreover, interest expenses will also increase significantly when interest rates return to a level more consistent with the sustained economic growth and the FOMC’s 2 percent long-run inflation objective.3
Figure 6 shows that most of the increase in spending that generated the persistent deficit over the 38 years before the financial crisis was spending for Medicare and Medicaid, particularly Medicare. Indeed, spending for Medicaid and Medicare increased from about 18 percent of mandatory spending in 1979 to 31 percent in 2011. During the same period, Social Security payments declined from 46 percent to 36 percent of mandatory spending despite the fact that mandatory spending increased significantly as a percent of total spending. Spending for income security increased from 14.5 percent to 20 percent; however, most of this increase was a consequence of the financial crisis and subsequent recession. Spending on income security was just
14 percent of total mandatory spending in 2007.
446

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

Thornton

Figure 6
Percent of Mandatory Spending by Category
Percent
60

Social Security
Medicare
Medicaid

50

Income Security
40

30

20

10

0
1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

These data show that the increase in the debt during the 38 years before the financial crisis was due to increased spending rather than decreased revenue. Furthermore, nearly all of the increased spending was in the form of transfer payments—that is, government payments to individuals for which the government receives no goods or services.

Sources of Government Revenue
This section evaluates the sources of government revenue to determine which taxes could be increased to resolve the deficit/debt problem. Currently, there are two main sources of government revenue—individual income taxes and Social Security taxes. Figure 7 shows the percent of government revenue for the 1979-2011 period by four categories: individual income taxes,
Social Security taxes, corporate income taxes, and other taxes (excise taxes, estate and gift taxes, customs duties, and miscellaneous receipts). As the figure shows, the percentages of total revenue from individual income and Social Security taxes have remained relatively constant over the period and together account for over 81 percent of total tax revenue. Corporate income tax revenue has also remained relatively constant at about 10 percent of total tax revenue.
When discussing taxes, it is important to distinguish between marginal and average tax rates. The marginal tax rate is the rate paid in taxes on each additional dollar of income earned.
The highest marginal income tax rate in the current tax code is 35 percent, which becomes effective on taxable income over $379,150. The average tax rate is simply the amount an individual pays in taxes divided by his or her income. Obviously, if the average tax rate goes up, tax revenue
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

447

Thornton

Figure 7
Percent of Government Revenue by Source
Percent
60

50

40

Individual Income

30

Corporate Income
Social Security
20

Other

10

0
1979 1981 1983 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011

Figure 8
Highest Marginal Individual Income Tax Rate and Individual Income Tax Revenue as a Percent of GDP
Percent of GDP
12

Percent
80
70

10
60
8
50
6

40
30

4
20
2

Highest Marginal Tax Rate (right axis)

10

Individual Income Tax Revenue/GDP (left axis)
0

0
1972 1974 1976 1978 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

448

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

Thornton

increases; however, the same is not necessarily true for marginal tax rates. That is, increasing marginal tax rates does not necessarily translate into additional tax revenue. This fact is illustrated in Figure 8, which shows the highest marginal individual tax rate in the U.S. tax code and individual income tax revenue as a percent of GDP from 1972 through 2011.4 As the figure shows, the numerous changes in marginal individual income tax rates have had little perceptible effect on tax revenue, either as a percent of GDP or individual income tax revenue as a percent of total tax revenue. The marginal tax rate over this period ranged from a high of 70 percent and a low of 30 percent with no marked change in individual income tax revenue as a percent of GDP. The exception appears to the Bush tax cuts, which lowered marginal tax rates for all income levels.
However, as noted previously, by 2007 individual income taxes increased relative to both GDP and total revenue to levels that are consistent with historical data. Hence, the experience since
2008 likely reflects the effect of the recession and the relatively anemic recovery. This result is a consequence of the extremely complicated U.S. tax laws that include a host of income deductions, tax expenditures, and tax credits, many of which vary with income levels; together these are referred to as tax loopholes.5 When marginal tax rates increase, individuals have a stronger incentive to manipulate their total tax by exploiting the loopholes.
Higher marginal tax rates also provide a stronger incentive for production to go “underground.” This is particularly true for the service sector and smaller businesses where it is much easier for transactions to be facilitated with cash so that some income can effectively be sheltered from taxes. In any event, there is only a weak relationship between marginal tax rates and tax revenue.
There is, however, a stronger connection between marginal tax rates and average tax rates at the individual level. Figure 9 shows average individual income tax rates by income quintiles and the highest 5 percent of income earners over the 1979-2007 period. The income measures are broad and include a wide variety of nonwage income.6 The dashed level lines denote the average tax rate for each income category for the 1979-2000 period, the period before the Bush tax cuts.
These data have several interesting features. First, average tax rates are progressive; that is, higherincome earners—individuals subject to higher marginal tax rates—paid a higher percentage of their income in taxes. Households with the highest 5 percent of income paid 17.6 percent of their income in federal income taxes in 2007, while those in the highest quintile had an average tax rate of 14.4 percent. Both of these tax rates are much lower than the 35 percent highest marginal tax rate in the tax code that year. Individuals in the middle quintile paid just 3.3 percent of their income in taxes, which is also much lower than the 15 percent marginal tax rate for households with a joint adjusted gross income over $15,100. Those in the two lowest quintiles had average tax rates of –0.4 percent and –6.8 percent. The negative average tax rates stem from a variety of tax credits available to lower-income earners. The net effect of these tax credits is to make the average tax rates across incomes nearly as progressive as the marginal tax rates: The difference in the average tax rates between the highest 5 percent of income earners and the lowest quintile in 2007 was 24.4 percent (17.6 percent – [–6.8 percent]) compared with the difference between the highest and lowest marginal tax rates, 25 percent (35 percent – 10 percent).
It is interesting to note that from 1979 through 2000 the average tax rate for the highest quintile and the top 5 percent of the income earners trended upward, while the average tax rate for the remaining quintiles trended down. Consequently, all of the changes in the tax code before
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

449

Thornton

Figure 9
Average Individual Income Tax Rates Paid by Households Based on Income (1979-2007)
Percent
20

15

10

5

0

–5

–10
1979

1981

1983

1st Quintile

1985

1987

2nd Quintile

1989

1991

3rd Quintile

1993

1995

1997

4th Quintile

1999

2001

5th Quintile

2003

2005

2007

Top 5 Percent

the Bush tax cuts effectively reduced the average tax rate for the bottom 80 percent of earners and raised the average tax rate for the top 20 percent. Hence, these tax changes appear to have redistributed the tax burden to the higher-income earners. In contrast, the Bush tax cuts reduced average tax rates for all income levels. However, these cuts reduced the average tax rates more for higher-income earners: From 2000 to 2007, the average tax rates declined by 3.1, 1.9, 1.7, 2, and 2 percentage points from the highest to the lowest quintiles, respectively.
The lowest-income earners have benefited the most from all tax law changes since 1979; the average tax rate declined by 1.3, 3.9, 4.2, 4.5, and 6.8 percentage points from the highest to the lowest quintiles, respectively. Moreover, since 2001 the lowest 40 percent of income earners have had zero or negative individual income average tax rates. Hence, 60 percent of income earners account for 100% of personal income tax revenue.
However, other federal taxes (e.g., Social Security taxes and excise taxes) that everyone pays affect the distribution of total taxes paid for various income levels. Figure 10 shows the average social insurance tax rates paid by individuals based on income quintiles. The average Social
Security tax for all quintiles increased until early 1993. The average Social Security tax rate continued to increase for the lowest-income earners but either leveled off or declined for everyone else. The behavior of the average Social Security tax rates across quintiles is due in part to the fact that there is a maximum level of income subject to Social Security taxes, which has changed over time. The maximum income subject to Social Security taxes increased from $22,900 in
1970 to $97,500 in 2007 and is $110,100 in 2012. If the maximum taxable income increases at a
450

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

Thornton

Figure 10
Average Social Security Insurance Tax Rates Paid by Households Based on Income (1979-2007)
Percent
12

10

8

6

4

2

0

1979

1981

1983

1st Quintile

1985

1987

2nd Quintile

1989

1991

3rd Quintile

1993

1995

1997

4th Quintile

1999

2001

5th Quintile

2003

2005

2007

Top 5 Percent

faster rate than incomes in a given quintile, the average tax rate for the quintile will tend to rise.
The rate of increase in maximum taxable income was very high in the early 1980s but declined to about 4 percent by the early 1990s and leveled off; the average rate of increase from 1991 through 2007 was 3.8 percent. Hence, the rise in average Social Security tax rates for all income levels before the early 1990s likely reflects the very rapid increase in the maximum taxable income during that period. As the growth rate of the maximum taxable income leveled off, the average tax rate leveled off for the middle three quintiles, declined for the top quintile, but continued to rise for the bottom quintile, suggesting that incomes for the bottom quintile continued to increase more slowly than the maximum taxable income.
The top 5 percent of income earners has had the lowest average social insurance tax rate over the entire period and the tax rate has been relatively constant. This is likely because these individuals have had incomes in excess of the maximum taxable income over the entire period.
The highest and lowest income quintiles had nearly identical average tax rates from 1979 to 1995, when the highest quintile’s average tax rate began to decline. This likely reflects the fact that with the maximum taxable income increasing more slowly, a larger percentage of individuals in the top quintile had incomes in excess of the maximum, so their average tax rate declined. The middle three quintiles had higher average tax rates than the lowest quintile and their average tax rates essentially leveled off after the early 1990s. The lower average Social Security tax rate paid by the lowest quintile reflects the fact that a larger part of their income comes from income not subject to Social Security taxes.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

451

Thornton

Figure 11
Average Total Federal Tax Rates by Income Quintiles
Percent
35

30

25

20

15

10

5

0
1979

1981

1983

1st Quintile

1985

1987

2nd Quintile

1989

1991

3rd Quintile

1993

1995

1997

4th Quintile

1999

2001

5th Quintile

2003

2005

2007

Top 5 Percent

In any event, the net effect of Social Security and other taxes is that the average total tax rate paid by all income quintiles is positive. Figure 11 shows the average total federal tax rate by quintiles and the top 5 percent of income earners. The conclusions discussed above, with respect to individual income taxes, generally hold for total federal taxes as well. The average total tax rates continue to be progressive, with the average tax rate increasing with income. One noticeable difference is that the relative gains from the Bush tax cuts are more uniform: The average tax rates declined by 2.9, 3.1, 2.3, 2.4, and 2.4 percent from the highest to lowest quintiles, respectively.

IMPLICATIONS FOR THE DEFICIT/DEBT PROBLEM DEBATE
I have argued that while the government’s responses to the financial crisis and the subsequent recession brought the U.S. deficit/debt problem to center stage, the root cause of the problem began four decades ago. Specifically, the deficit/debt problem began circa 1970 when the government broke with long-standing tradition and began running a persistent deficit. I then showed that the persistent deficits occurred because spending increased significantly relative to GDP, while revenue increased only slightly: The government increased spending without a commensurate increase in revenue. Finally, I used available information on government revenue to establish some basic facts about the sources of government revenue and who is currently bearing the
452

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

Thornton

tax burden. This section uses these basic facts to illustrate some important issues in the debate about how best to keep the deficit/debt problem from becoming a deficit/debt crisis.
The fact that most of the increase in deficit spending can be attributed to increases in
Medicare, and to a lesser extent Medicaid, has led some to suggest that a resolution of the deficit/ debt problem will require significant cuts in these programs, especially Medicare. This conclusion is bolstered by projections that Medicare costs will increase faster than income as the population ages and medical science advances.
Of course, that need not happen. Society could just as well decide to increase revenue by raising taxes. There are several issues here: How much will taxes have to be increased to keep the problem from becoming a crisis? Which taxes will be increased? Who will pay the higher taxes? The first question is very difficult to answer with any degree of precision; however, there seems to be a consensus that, barring significant spending cuts, taxes would have to be increased substantially. Since most of the government’s revenue comes from social insurance and personal income taxes, it is reasonable to expect that these taxes will have to be increased significantly. Who should pay higher taxes? Some suggest that it should be those at the higher income levels. However, the analysis above shows that (i) the top 60 percent of the income earners have an average effective federal tax rate that is about four times larger than that of the bottom 40 percent of the income earners and (ii) the average personal tax rates and effective federal tax rates are already relatively progressive. Consequently, some are leery about the benefits of making it even more so.
One tax that is somewhat regressive is social insurance tax. The regressivity stems from the fact that there is a maximum income level to which the tax is applied. Consequently, the regressivity of the tax could be significantly reduced or eliminated by simply significantly increasing that limit or by removing the limit altogether. The problem with this suggestion is, of course, that benefits are linked to the amount of the contributions (i.e., taxes paid). Consequently, if higher-income earners were to pay significantly more for social insurance, their benefits on retirement should also increase.
Income taxes are typically raised by increasing marginal tax rates. However, the relationship between changes in marginal tax rates and changes in income tax revenue are relatively weak.
Hence, increasing marginal tax rates on a particular group of income earners will not necessarily result in a significant increase in total tax revenue. Moreover, basic economic theory shows that higher marginal tax rates could reduce output and, thereby, tax revenue. Consequently, the total revenue relative to GDP could be little affected by the change in the marginal tax rate. This, of course, gives rise to the possibility that lower marginal taxes could actually increase total tax revenue. Some analysts suggest that all of these potential problems can be reduced or eliminated by a significant revision of the U.S. tax code. Specifically, these analysts suggest the elimination of most, if not all, of the income deductions and tax credits that currently exist in the tax code.
They suggest that most of these deductions and credits, such as the deductibility of interest paid on mortgages, benefit higher-income groups and consequently are regressive. In any event, they suggest that if most of these deductions and credits were eliminated, the existing system of a schedule of marginal tax rates could be replaced with a single and relatively low tax rate. Proponents suggest that the so-called flat tax would increase the incentive to work and would result in a more equitable distribution of the tax burden based on income. For example, an individual
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

November/December 2012

453

Thornton

with an annual taxable income of $40,000 would pay $4,000 in taxes if the tax rate were 10 percent; a person with a taxable income of $4 million would pay $400,000 in taxes.
Finally, the long-run perspective offered here shows that there is a deeper and more fundamental issue that must be addressed if the problem is to be resolved solely or primarily by raising taxes. Specifically, the analysis shows that the deficit/debt problem began when the government decided to increase spending significantly without increasing taxes. If the problem is resolved by increasing taxes to a higher percentage of GDP to match current expenditures, there would be no guarantee that the government would not simply increase spending further, thereby starting down a path to the next deficit/debt problem. The long-run perspective suggests there can be no permanent solution to the deficit/debt problem until a mechanism can be established that prevents the government from running persistent deficits. Indeed, this is the intention of the
European Fiscal Compact, which was signed by all but two of the European Union members on
March 2, 2012.7 The Fiscal Compact requires signing members to enact laws requiring national budgets to be in balance or surplus and the laws must provide a self-correcting mechanism to prevent their breach. Of course, the nature of these self-correcting mechanisms is yet to be determined, as is the extent to which they can be breached and the nature of the penalty associated with their being breached. In any event, the longer-run perspective suggests that without some mechanism, any resolution that does not involve significant and permanent cuts in spending may only be temporary.

NOTES
1

The deficit/debt problem will become the deficit/debt crisis when the federal government has to pay a significant premium to finance the debt. For example, Greece’s deficit/debt problem became a crisis in late 2009 when the rates it had to pay on its borrowing tripled in less than a year.

2

Much of the analysis in this section is from Kliesen and Thornton (2011a,b).

3

See Thornton (2011).

4

For additional analysis, see Kliesen and Thornton (2011c).

5

Also see Reynolds (2011).

6

The income measure, comprehensive household income, consists of pretax cash income plus income from other sources. Pretax cash income is the sum of wages, salaries, self-employment income, rents, taxable and nontaxable interest, dividends, realized capital gains, cash transfer payments, and retirement benefits plus taxes paid by businesses and employee contributions to 401(k) retirement plans. Other sources of income include all in-kind benefits
(Medicare, Medicaid, employer-paid health insurance premiums, food stamps, school lunches/breakfasts, and housing and energy assistance).

7

The Czech Republic and the United Kingdom did not sign the compact.

REFERENCES
Gokhale, Jagadeesh and Smetters, Kent. Fiscal and Generational Imbalances: New Budget Measures for New Budget
Priorities. Jackson, TN: AEI Press, 2003.
Kliesen, Kevin L. and Thornton, Daniel L. “The Federal Debt: Too Little Revenue or Too Much Spending?” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses, 2011a, No. 20, July 7, 2011; http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/es/11/ES1120.pdf. 454

November/December 2012

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

References: Gokhale, Jagadeesh and Smetters, Kent. Fiscal and Generational Imbalances: New Budget Measures for New Budget Priorities. Jackson, TN: AEI Press, 2003. Kliesen, Kevin L. and Thornton, Daniel L. “The Federal Debt: Too Little Revenue or Too Much Spending?” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Economic Synopses, 2011a, No. 20, July 7, 2011; http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/es/11/ES1120.pdf. 454 November/December 2012 Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis REVIEW

You May Also Find These Documents Helpful

  • Good Essays

    Since the very beginning, the nation has started out with a debt from the American Revolution. Only once in the entire U.S. history the debt was at zero and it was during President Andrew Jackson’s administration in the 1830s. President Jackson was able to achieve this because he was a supporter…

    • 913 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Better Essays

    The United States current economic status has improved from 2010 to 2012, as far as, unemployment rates, consumer income, and (lower) interest rates are concerned. When we examine the Gross Domestic Product, we are continuing to increase the United States debts. In 2009, the United States estimated GDP (purchasing power parity) was $14.38 trillion, which increased $0.44 trillion in 2010. From 2010, the GDP at $14.82 trillion increased $0.22 trillion, putting the U.S. at 15.04 trillion in debt (Stephanie Mandell, 2012).…

    • 1516 Words
    • 6 Pages
    Better Essays
  • Satisfactory Essays

    The argument’s main idea is that the U.S. debt is continuing to increase, and the government needs to halt this growth. The author, Kimberly Amadeo, begins her argument by explaining that the U.S. debt is held by the American public and the governments of other countries. Our debt is the largest in the world, and is continuing to increase. The article also explains how the debt became so massive. Amadeo states that the debt is caused by an accumulation of Federal budget deficits and presidents borrowing from the Social Security Trust Fund. Also, other countries keep lending money to the U.S. and set low interest rates, which benefits the Federal government. Finally, Congress keeps increasing the limit on the debt, thus allowing it to continue to grow. The author supports these reasons by using facts and statistics. The article is wrapped up by explaining that the economy may be thriving now, but soon the growing debt will cause a major crash.…

    • 314 Words
    • 2 Pages
    Satisfactory Essays
  • Good Essays

    In our hearts, we all know that the ONLY way to stop the growth in the federal debt is to stop spending more money than the government receives. Thus, me must reduce government spending AND increase taxes. The plan is as simple as that.…

    • 1050 Words
    • 5 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    National Debt Cons

    • 1527 Words
    • 7 Pages

    At 9:58 p.m. on April 13th, 2016 the nation debt clock rang in at about $19,243,130,456,985 dollars in debt; and growing. The government seems to try and lower the debt everyday but nothing seems to be working. Even before the United States of America became an official country, the national…

    • 1527 Words
    • 7 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Satisfactory Essays

    Ferguson paper

    • 368 Words
    • 2 Pages

    The United States’ resources, time, effort, money and strategic involvement with allies should be of upmost important because currently the United States is heavily in debt. As of September 25, (2014) over…

    • 368 Words
    • 2 Pages
    Satisfactory Essays
  • Good Essays

    Secondly, another way to reduce debt is to completely cut out all the useless spending. In a year, the government spends $2.6 million dollars to help “Chinese prostitutes to drink more responsibly on the job.” (reference) Why waste money on prostitutes? Why does the American government care enough to help them? We could be putting that $2.6 million towards out national debt. It’s not much but anything and everything will help. The…

    • 906 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Better Essays

    Balanced Budget Amendment

    • 1333 Words
    • 6 Pages

    There is a lot of debate for a Balanced Budget Amendment in the United States. The trade-off between “discipline” and “flexibility” is at the core of the debate surrounding the establishment of a Balanced Budget Amendment[2]. Those who oppose a Balanced Budget Amendment argue that it may…

    • 1333 Words
    • 6 Pages
    Better Essays
  • Good Essays

    It is a critical role in our country’s financial system. As a citizen, we should care about the national debt because of this debt; it affects our Social Security, Medicare, and our health care. Not caring about our national debt can result in a significant recession. Social media will cover about budget cuts, but what we do not see is a decrease in government spending. The debt needs to be addressed to make changes gradually, and it will make it easier on the economy to adjust.…

    • 839 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Good Essays

    The United States government does not need any more debt. Just like every family in America knows, sometimes you have to limit your spending when times are tough. Unlike our President, who insists on spending as much money as possible, just letting the next generation take on the load of debt. It was not in…

    • 835 Words
    • 3 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Better Essays

    Us National Debt

    • 1057 Words
    • 5 Pages

    An ongoing American issue that affects every American today is the U. S. National Debt crisis. Although many of us hear about it every day on the news, many truly don’t know the ramifications of the very critical ongoing issue. The U.S. National debt affects consumers every day, in just about every imaginable way but probably most notably in Americans facing higher taxes, higher interest rates, and the U.S. government cutting back on services, weaker job markets, and lastly inflation. These five issues are just a few of many ways that the U.S. National Debt affects consumers on a daily basis.…

    • 1057 Words
    • 5 Pages
    Better Essays
  • Good Essays

    Consumerism

    • 855 Words
    • 4 Pages

    "Any time the urge strikes, we now have the capability to act on it impulsively, and that creates a much greater challenge for us than was ever the case before," says psychologist Stuart Vyse, PhD, author of "Going Broke: Why Americans Can't Hold On To Their Money" (Oxford University Press, 2008). "It's only natural that we are having trouble with debt."…

    • 855 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    results of the debt. It is a look at both the factual causes and the arguments…

    • 1109 Words
    • 5 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Good Essays

    The video is a well demonstration of debt issues that the U.S. government faces. It starts with the tough economic condition that Obama inherited from Bush. Then, it talks about Bush’s centerpiece economic agenda: cut taxes, as well as the way Bush always put politics ahead of economics. After a serious of expenses related to two big wars; two enormous tax cuts; and a variety of new entitlement program signed by Bush had been spent, the economic began to go down. He not only squandered the entire budget surplus he had inherited, but started to confronting a stubborn recession and a steadily escalating budget deficit. Next, the video shows the bitterly partisan fight over Obama’s expensive economic recovery plan. The Republicans worried about if the plan goes well, they will get no credits for anything they have done. So they strongly disagree with this huge amount of recovery expenses. The main issue regarding of this plan is about reform healthcare in order to save money in the long run. However, it is difficult to persuade interest groups and politicians who have been battling over healthcare for a long time. Besides, it is especially tough to talk to Americans about the government are going to spend less on benefits in a recession time. In the end, this video talks about Obama’s budget, and the rigorous debt deficit condition that the U.S. is going through.…

    • 669 Words
    • 3 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Good Essays

    “It is not about how hard you fall, but how you get up and keep going.” Economic recession may be a natural phenomenon in the world’s economies. Every market has its peaks and falls, definitely the United States of America has hers.…

    • 980 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Good Essays