Top-Rated Free Essay
Preview

Literature Review on Microinsurance

Powerful Essays
13359 Words
Grammar
Grammar
Plagiarism
Plagiarism
Writing
Writing
Score
Score
Literature Review on Microinsurance
MICROINSURANCE PAPER No. 1

LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE
Stefan Dercon*^ and Martina Kirchberger* in collaboration with Jan Willem Gunning^ and Jean-Philippe Platteau^
*Oxford University ^European Development Research Network (EUDN)

i
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

MICROINSURANCE PAPER No. 1

Copyright © International Labour Organization 2008 First published 2008 Publications of the International Labour Office enjoy copyright under Protocol 2 of the Universal Copyright Convention. Nevertheless, short excerpts from them may be reproduced without authorization, on condition that the source is indicated. For rights of reproduction or translation, application should be made to ILO Publications (Rights and Permissions), International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland, or by email: pubdroit@ilo.org. The International Labour Office welcomes such applications. Libraries, institutions and other users registered with reproduction rights organizations may make copies in accordance with the licences issued to them for this purpose. Visit www.ifrro.org to find the reproduction rights organization in your country.

ILO Cataloguing in Publication Data Dercon, Stefan; Kirchberger, Martina; Gunning, Jan Willem; Platteau, Jean Philippe Literature review on microinsurance / Stefan Dercon and Martina Kirchberger in collaboration with Jan Willem Gunning and Jean-Philippe Platteau ; International Labour Office. - Geneva: ILO, 2008 33 p. (Microinsurance paper ; no.1) ISBN: 9789221330459 (web pdf) International Labour Office microinsurance / literature survey 11.02.3

October 2008

ILO Cataloguing in Publication Data

The designations employed in ILO publications, which are in conformity with United Nations practice, and the presentation of material therein do not imply the expression of any opinion whatsoever on the part of the International Labour Office concerning the legal status of any country, area or territory or of its authorities, or concerning the delimitation of its frontiers. The responsibility for opinions expressed in signed articles, studies and other contributions rests solely with their authors, and publication does not constitute an endorsement by the International Labour Office of the opinions expressed in them. Reference to names of firms and commercial products and processes does not imply their endorsement by the International Labour Office, and any failure to mention a particular firm, commercial product or process is not a sign of disapproval. ILO publications and electronic products can be obtained through major booksellers or ILO local offices in many countries, or direct from ILO Publications, International Labour Office, CH-1211 Geneva 22, Switzerland. Catalogues or lists of new publications are available free of charge from the above address, or by email: pubvente@ilo.org Visit our website: www.ilo.org/publns

LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

MICROINSURANCE PAPER No. 1

PREFACE
The primary goal of the International Labour Organization (ILO) is to contribute with member States to achieve full and productive employment and decent work for all. The Decent Work Agenda comprises four interrelated areas: respect for fundamental worker’s rights and international labour standards, employment promotion, social protection and social dialogue. Broadening the employment and social protection opportunities of poor people through financial markets is an urgent undertaking. Housed at the ILO’s Social Finance Programme, the Microinsurance Innovation Facility seeks to increase the availability of quality insurance for the developing world’s low-income families to help them guard against risk and overcome poverty. The Facility, launched in 2008 with the support of a grant from the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, supports the Global Employment Agenda implemented by the ILO’s Employment Sector. Research on microinsurance is still at an embryonic stage, with many questions to be asked and options to be tried before solutions on how to protect significant numbers of the world’s poor against risk begin to emerge. The Microinsurance Innovation Facility’s research programme provides an opportunity to explore the potential and challenges of microinsurance. The Facility’s Microinsurance Papers series aims to document and disseminate key learnings from our partners’ research activities. More knowledge is definitely needed to tackle key challenges and foster innovation in microinsurance. The Microinsurance Papers cover wide range of topics on demand, supply and impact of microinsurance that are relevant for both practitioners and policymakers. The views expressed are the responsibility of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent those of the ILO.

José Manuel Salazar-Xirinachs Executive Director Employment Sector

ii
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

MICROINSURANCE PAPER No. 1

CONTENTS
Preface............................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................ii Acknowledgements................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................iv Summary......................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................v 1 Introduction....................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................1 2 Risk and its implications for poverty.................................................................................................................................................................................................................................2 3 Impact of Microinsurance...................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................4 4 Demand for Microinsurance Products........................................................................................................................................................................................................................9 5 Supply................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................13 Bibliography...................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................................17 Annex : Overview of selected micro insurance programmes................................................................................................................................................................23

iii
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

MICROINSURANCE PAPER No. 1

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
This paper has benefited from helpful discussions with and support from Craig Churchill and Michal Matul and other members of the ILO Microinsurance Innovation Facility team, as well as from discussions with participants of a workshop at ILO, more specifically Stephan Klasen, Gaby Ramm, Brandon Mathews, Valerie Schmitt-Diabate, Carla Henry, and Bernd Balkenhol. Useful comments were also obtained from Monique Cohen, Ralf Radermacher and Rupalee Ruchismita. The authors are responsible for any errors.

iv
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

MICROINSURANCE PAPER No. 1

SUMMARY
This paper provides a selective overview of the current state of research on microinsurance. Its key purpose is to identify knowledge gaps, that deserve further investigation. The review is structured along three core issues: the need for careful evaluation of the impact of microinsurance on the poor, the need to increase our understanding of the nature of the demand for microinsurance, including dimensions related to trust and the understanding of insurance by the poor, and finally, the need for further research on supply dimensions, focusing on the key challenges and bottlenecks for widespread and sustainable provision of microinsurance. For each of these core issues, a brief review of the literature is offered, as well as the questions that could guide further work, informing the research agenda of the Microinsurance Innovation Facility.

v
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

1 > INTRODUCTION
Uninsured risk leaves poor households vulnerable to serious or even catastrophic losses from negative shocks. It also forces them to undertake costly strategies to manage their incomes and assets in the face of risk, lowering mean incomes earned. Welfare costs due to shocks and foregone profitable opportunities have been found to be substantial, contributing to persistent poverty (Morduch, 1990; Dercon, 1996, 2004; Rosenzweig and Binswanger, 1993; Elbers et al., 2007, Pan, 2008). Microinsurance has the potential to reduce these welfare costs. By offering a payout when an insured loss occurs, it avoids other costly ways of coping with the shock leaving future income earning opportunities intact. Furthermore, the security linked to being insured can be expected to allow the avoidance of costly risk-management strategies with positive impacts on poverty reduction. This literature review provides an overview of the current state of research on microinsurance, identifies key knowledge gaps and develops a conceptual framework to inform and organize the research agenda of the Microinsurance Facility in the area of impact evaluation, demand and supply issues. For the purpose of this review, microinsurance is defined in line with Churchill (2006) as an insurance that (i) operates by risk-pooling (ii) is financed through regular premiums and is (iii) tailored to the poor who would otherwise not be able to take out insurance. The main focus of the literature review is on voluntary insurance1. Other ways through which individuals or the public sector can insure against risks, such as precautionary savings, access to credit or through public safety nets are therefore not treated in detail in this review. However, this leads already to one key omission in the existing literature: generally, the benefits of microinsurance are not compared to alternative mechanisms that may provide insurance-like benefits, possibly in a more costeffective way, such as microsavings, consumer or emergency credit, and public safety nets. This paper is divided into four parts. The first section offers a general framework to understand the link between risk and poverty, allowing us to carve out a clear place for insurance activities as part of poverty eradication efforts. It also summarises some of the key findings related to the work on risk and its consequences for households, communities and firms. Part two deals with evaluating the impact of microinsurance and develops a general conceptual framework for impact analysis applicable to various types of insurances. It reviews some of the (few) papers that have been able to assess the overall impact of insurance on welfare outcomes. Part three reviews demand side issues: is there a demand for insurance, and what (if anything) constrains this demand to be reflected in actual uptake of insurance products. Areas considered relate to the actual cost and pricing of microinsurance, the credibility of the provider, and the issue of information and knowledge about risk and insurance. Part four reviews key supply side challenges, such as effective product development, pricing, marketing and sale, institutional models and delivery channels as well as technology options. An overview of studies reviewing a range of microinsurance programmes is presented in the Annex. It is important to highlight that, while different insurance products are discussed at the same time, readers should keep in mind major differences between health insurance and other types of insurance such as life, property or rainfall insurance. The latter products can typically be seen as only dependent on the appropriate functioning and management of the insurance system itself. The impact on clients will depend on whether incomes, assets or other outcomes are better protected with the product rather than without. Health insurance is more complicated. The impact of health insurance is most appropriately assessed in terms of health, but this is directly dependent on the strength and weaknesses of the health care provision, and not just the financial side of the insurance scheme. For example, factors such as the structure of health service delivery system, its financing, monitoring and regulation play a crucial role in determining health insurance performance (Preker, 2007).
1

This includes voluntary insurance sold to groups with mandatory within-group membership.

1
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

2 > RISK AND ITS IMPLICATIONS FOR POVERTY
To understand the impact of insurance initiatives, it is instructive to put it in the context of how risk shapes behaviour and outcomes of the poor. Table 1 offers a simple framework (based on Dercon, 2008), linking risk to its consequences in terms of outcomes in various dimensions of welfare in the short and long run. Households, communities, firms or societies as a whole, face a multitude of risks. Given their options and characteristics, they will make “risk management decisions”, or at least decisions with implications for risk management. This decision-making ‘ex-ante’ (when risk is present) has implications for outcomes, in the short run and long run, which will be discussed below further. Next, shocks may occur – effectively a realisation of the state of the world whose risk may or may not have been recognised beforehand. People’s responses or inability to respond will again have implications for outcomes, in the short run and in the long run. It is worth emphasising that two distinct ‘decision moments’ are considered: one when there is still ‘risk’ (i.e. a potentially large number of different possible events or circumstances), and one when a ‘shock’ (i.e. a realisation of one of these possible events or circumstances) has occurred. The decisions that need to be taken in the face of risk (risk management or ‘ex-ante’ strategies) are potentially very different from those taken in the face of a shock (risk coping or ‘ex-post’ strategies). Nevertheless, they cannot be viewed independently, as risk management decisions will have implications for the possible set of risk coping strategies, while risk coping will have implications for the type of risk management decisions that can be taken in the next period. Table 1 Risk and outcomes Implications for WELFARE OUTCOMES In the SHORT RUN In the LONG RUN SHOCK “realisation of the state of the world” Implications for WELFARE OUTCOMES In the SHORT RUN In the LONG RUN

UNINSURED RISK ‘sources of risk’

risk management decisions

‘risk coping’ decisions

What risk strategies are commonly observed? Table 2 summarises some of the evidence, highlighting some survey articles of the vast literature available. A number of recent survey articles have summarised some of the key strategies observed. These strategies have been widely acknowledged as a central part of people’s livelihoods. Households have strategies to cope ex-post with shocks, to smooth consumption and nutrition when shocks happen, even if formal credit and insurance markets, or social protection schemes are not available. They may use savings, often in the form of live animals, built up as part of a precautionary strategy against risk. They may develop personalised informal credit arrangements. They also often engage in informal mutual support networks, for example, clan- or neighbourhood-based associations, or even more formal groups such as funeral societies.2 However, group-based systems cannot work effectively in the face of ‘covariant’ shocks, affecting the whole group, while the lack of good stores of wealth, with limited risks, also means that building these ‘buffer stocks’ is highly costly and indeed not as effective as hoped for. On the latter, a well-known example is when households in Northern Wollo in Ethiopia tried to use their standard smoothing device – selling small and larger livestock – to cope with the drought and famine in the mid-1980s. Livestock prices collapsed due to oversupply and lack of demand, in the face of high grain prices, providing a classic case of entitlement failures as in Sen (1981). In terms of risk management strategies, different forms of diversification are commonly observed – either in crops, activities or assets. As long as the returns to these activities are not perfectly covariate, there will be benefits from diversification.
2 In particular in economics, the ‘consumption smoothing’ and ‘risk-sharing’ literature has thrived, and indeed they are examples where work on developing countries has heavily influenced the mainstream research agenda. Surveys of this literature are found in Townsend (1995) or Deaton (1997); as well as in Dercon (2005) and Morduch (1995).

2
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Specialisation in low risk, low return activities is another strategy, usually when alternatives are all involving considerable risks.3 Families will also build up extra savings in the face of risk (precautionary savings) with the result that less resources are available for consumption and other necessary spending. Table 2. Cost of risk: a review Theme Selected references
Ex-ante risk management mechanisms Reviews in: Morduch (1995) Dercon (2005) Reviews in Townsend (1995) Morduch (1999) Dercon (2005) Asset accumulation Rosenzweig and Wolpin (1993), Elbers, Gunning, Kinsey (2007), Elbers, Gunning, Pan (2008), Pan (2008) Nutrition and Health Gertler and Gruber (2002) Hoddinott and Kinsey (2001), Dercon and Hoddinott (2005), Lybbert et al. (2004), Alderman et al. (2006)

Ex-post risk coping mechanisms

Nature of the Evidence Risk management is common, via diversification or entry into low risk, low return activities. Risk reduction at the cost of lower mean incomes . Lower mean consumption spending due to precautionary savings. Poverty persistence. Evidence of use of assets to smooth consumption, and informal sharing of risk within communities; overall only partial smoothing of shocks, especially related to covariate shocks

Impact beyond consumption or income

Lower accumulation of assets due to risk, mainly due to ex-ante responses; effects of portfolio composition of assets, such as higher liquid assets rather than higher return illiquid assets. losses in health and nutrition, especially due to large shocks, such as drought or catastrophic events.

Much research on the effectiveness of these strategies is still taking place, documenting and analysing different rather sophisticated mechanisms used in poor societies around the world. But the key finding seems to stand: they provide some protection against risk and shocks; however, this protection is never more than partial, and considerable risks remain (Morduch, 1999). In short, this literature clearly opens the door for a policy focus: how to design better protection schemes, as informal mechanisms are not offering perfect protection. This framework also allows us to emphasise that costs are not just incurred in the short run, via fluctuations in welfare outcomes. Risk coping strategies come at a cost, as assets are depleted when trying to cope with risk. Examples are sales of livestock during crises, going with less food, potentially affecting long-term health and nutrition, not least of children, or withdrawing children from school affecting long-term human capital. Furthermore, ex-ante strategies can be very costly, for example limiting the use of modern inputs or in general holding less than efficient asset portfolios or just less accumulation of assets (Elbers, Gunning and Kinsey, 2007; Dercon and Christiaensen, 2007). The result is that risk can be a cause of persistent poverty, with consequences not just limited to temporary welfare costs. This nature of the benefits of insurance initiatives in the context of its actual benefits for poor households can then be directly seen. Insurance can offer a means of coping with the consequences of shocks, allowing smoothing of nutrition or avoiding costly asset depletion. It also allows the poor to take advantage of opportunities that would help them to escape poverty but that are too risky without additional protection. At the same time, from this framework it is also clear that insurance is only one of many possibilities to

3 It is not just individuals and communities that develop risk strategies. Firms in developing countries also have been observed to respond to risk. For example, firms adjust their stock management policies in line with a precautionary motive, so that they can use it as a risk coping strategy (Fafchamps et al., 2000); labour market contracts in firms reflect risk-sharing arrangements, i.e. workers and firms share risk, just as informal village institutions (Bigsten et al., 2004). Firms have also been observed to change in the face of risk of corruption, their investment portfolio away from easily expropriated assets (Svensson, 2003). Of course, the latter would be a risk for which the response is unlikely to be to offer insurance contracts.

3
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

reduce the impact of risk on poverty. Clearly, other financial instruments could be beneficial too, such as better and more flexible savings products (strengthening self insurance and risk coping) or better credit possibilities (such as emergency and consumption credit products). Furthermore, stronger social protection systems, such as forms of social security or safety nets, could offer similar credible alternatives. The review below will also highlight numerous problems with insurance provision, so developing insurance may also involve considerable costs and ensuring that insurance products are taken up by clients may be difficult to achieve for other reasons than just costs. In short, there may well be trade-offs that would make insurance not necessarily the optimal response. More research is clearly needed to pinpoint exactly the circumstances and conditions in which efforts to expand insurance offer broader benefits to households than other alternatives. As a result, besides offering a review of the literature on microinsurance, we offer below also a number of research questions that deserve more work.

3 > IMPACT OF MICROINSURANCE
In this section, we turn to the evaluation of the impact of specific insurance products, and provide a number of key research questions deserving further attention. The impact of microinsurance products can be measured in a number of dimensions: first, the level of protection the insurance provides when a shock occurs (ex-post); for example, how well does a health insurance protect households from catastrophic spending in case of serious illness of a household member? It directly impacts households’ ex-post risk coping mechanisms and is the prime justification for households to take up insurance: it helps households to keep consumption spending stable and avoid asset loss. The impact of microinsurance on consumption, assets or other dimensions of welfare (such as health, nutrition, school enrolment) is therefore a useful indicator to investigate the role of microinsurance in allowing individuals to avoid further poverty and hardship4. Indicators can be measured at the relevant client-level, including the household level or different members within the household, allowing the exploration of gender or within-household allocation effects. Second, microinsurance can impact on households’ behaviour before shocks occur (ex-ante). As discussed above, a large part of the costs of uninsured risk for poor households are due to costly ex-ante risk management strategies. The question arises whether insurance helps clients to redirect their activities and assets to entrepreneurial, higher return even if more risky portfolios. Here the focus could be on the type of activities households are involved in, their asset accumulation behaviour and the composition of assets. At the same time, given moral hazard, insurance may affect behaviours in more negative ways reducing the potential benefits, such as being less careful with crops or property, unless products are designed to counter this. In the case of health, insurance could impact on health seeking behaviour, including prevention, and depending on the nature and incentives entailed in the product and the organisation and quality of the health care system, impacts could be very different. A further issue that is important to consider relates to the impacts of taking up microinsurance across households and individuals – who benefits most? Clearly, microinsurance evaluation should not just be interested in average impacts across a population, but gain understanding on the type of clients and their family members for whom insurance offers most benefits. One could study the impact by socioeconomic background, ethnicity, gender dimensions, and other well-defined characterisations. Finally, the provision of microinsurance schemes could have indirect effects on existing systems of protection, such as informal insurance and mutual support mechanisms in the communities involved. For example, other informal insurance systems may be affected and undermined, possibly with detrimental impacts on some households and individuals.

4

Wagstaff (2008) discusses methods for measurement of financial protection in health.

4
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Table 3 presents a number of studies that managed to evaluate a number of insurance schemes in a methodologically sound way, focusing on impact dimensions beyond just the purchase of insurance. Overall, this set of studies is clearly very limited and one could argue that some others should have been included, but it is in any case correct that there are few studies that can really credibly evaluate the welfare or other benefits from insurance. Table 3. An overview of key microinsurance impact evaluations on clients Theme Available research Nature of the Evidence Impact of weather insurance on modern input use: Gine and Yang No increased risk-taking in the form of modern (2007) input use in Malawi. Impact on ex-ante risk management Impact of health insurance on Decrease in precautionary savings due to precautionary savings: (Gruber health insurance and Yelowitz, 1999; Chou et al., 2003) Positive impact of health insurance on anthropometric status in Vietnam.
Insurance protects against payments for inpatient care, but does not decrease out of pocket expenditures for outpatient care. Impact on health of health insurance: Wagstaff and Pradhan (2005) Chankova et al. (2008); Dong (1999); Dror et al. (2006); Gumber, (2001); Jütting (2004), Preker et al. (2002); Ranson (2001), Wagstaff (2007), Wagstaff et al. (2007) Direct evidence of other insurance mechanisms on specific welfare dimensions is limited or missing. Differential treatment (drug prescription) between insured and uninsured individuals in China due to financing. Micro-health insurance units contribute to smaller differences in access to health care among according to income in the Philippines. Reduced out-of-pocket expenditures for members of community health insurances, but exclusion of the poorest in Senegal. Increase in service utilization and inpatient care, but no reduction in out-of-pocket expenditures in Vietnam. Increase in service utilization but no impact on out-of-pocket expenditures and utilization among the poor. Uptake of weather insurance (India, Malawi): Gine et al, 2007b; Gine and Yang 2007; Uptake of health insurance: Wagstaff and Pradhan, 2005; Jowett, 2003 Impact on informal insurance schemes (externalities) Attanasio and Rios-Rull (2000) (theory); Dercon and Krishnan (2003) (safety net) Jowett (2003) (health insurance in Vietnam).

Success of insurance in offering ex-post risk coping

Heterogeneity of Impact (profiles of who benefits most)

Signs that relatively not-so-poor households take up more insurance.

Possible crowding out by microinsurance of informal insurance. Evidence in Ethiopia is suggestive of this risk, albeit in the context of a safety net, not in terms of insurance. Evidence in Vietnam shows that strong informal insurance hinders uptake of new insurance products.

Impact on existing informal mechanisms and other external effects

5
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

So far, the literature evaluating the impact of insurance in low-income countries is not just relatively limited; it is also rather unbalanced between different types of insurances. The main emphasis has been on different types of health insurance schemes, and their impact on health care-utilization, out-of-pockets expenditure or social inclusion (Chankova et al., 2008; Dong, 1999; Dror et al., 2006; Gumber, 2001; Jowett et al., 2003; Jütting, 2004, Preker et al., 2002; Ranson, 2001, Wagstaff, 2007, Wagstaff et al, 2007). Very few studies evaluate the impact of insurance on overall household income, nutrition, or other dimensions of welfare than those directly related to the insurance. Exceptions include Wagstaff and Pradhan (2005), who evaluate the impact of health insurance on health outcomes (anthropometric indicators), health care utilization and nonmedical consumption expenditure for households in Vietnam using panel data and propensity score matching. They find that voluntary health insurance had a positive impact on height-for-age and weight-forage of young school children, and led to an increase in non-medical household consumption. Building on Gruber and Yelowitz (1999)’s evidence from Medicaid in the U.S., Chou et al. (2003) find that public health insurance in Taiwan has caused a reduction in savings for precautionary reasons, with the effect negatively proportional to the size of savings. Careful evaluations on the impact of microinsurance in the field of life, property, livestock and weather on the poor are scarcer. Young et al. (2006) highlight the lack of even a standard framework in which to measure the impact of microinsurance, as well as difficulties with measuring its impact. For example, if a shock forces a household to sell livestock, despite insurance, but insurance allows it to sell it later and at a better price, the additional benefit of insurance is not straightforward to measure. In fact, this is just one example of the key problems with evaluating insurance schemes: it is perfectly possible that in the period evaluated, few if any may face serious losses, and in that case, those paying the premium may in fact have lower outcomes than those not buying insurance. In general, evaluative work is hindered by the lack of systematic baseline data on beneficiaries and plausible control groups. The increased use of randomized experiments and the careful use of panel data to allow constructing comparable treatment and control groups will provide scope for much progress. Below, we summarise some of the key methodological challenges. In the field of weather insurance, recently a number of interesting randomised experiments have tried to asses their impact on incomes and also on risk-taking behaviour (Gine et al., 2007a; 2007b; Gine and Yang, 2007). The findings do not show substantial impacts; for example, Gine and Yang (2007) undertake a study in Malawi and show that those with insurance did not increase the uptake of risky technologies, one of the expected outcomes. In terms of the impact of new schemes on existing mechanisms, Jowett et al. (2003) find that social cohesion and informal financial networks are negatively associated with insurance uptake, suggesting that the former crowd out public voluntary health insurance. Dercon and Krishnan (2003) present evidence that suggests a crowding out effect of informal risk-sharing arrangements by food aid. While the evidence base is limited, microinsurance can also have important externalities at the community level. For example, health insurance can produce positive information externalities through improved preventive behavior so that also individuals who are not insured benefit from it. On the other hand, Morduch (2006) points towards a possible negative price effect of insurance during times of shocks when insured individuals drive up the price of goods, for example food. In conclusion, there are few studies that rigorously evaluate the welfare or other benefits from insurance. A key issue is methodological: it is very hard to evaluate such programmes. To conclude this section, a list of questions and avenues for further research is offered. Box 1 further below discusses relevant methodological issues in addressing these evaluation questions.

6
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

This list of questions is written generically, for any type of product. This will not be always sensible. Different risks have specific features, and as would have feasible insurance products for different risks. Specificity should be taken into account when studying the impact of products. For example, moral hazard may be more problematic in the case of crop insurance (farmers may feel less inclined to try to salvage their crops when insured) compared to life insurance (as insurance is unlikely to affect mortality risk systematically). Adverse selection may be a bigger problem in the case of health insurance than, say, crop insurance (for example, drought risks may well be more similar in a community than health risks). Such factors will affect the nature of the products that can be offered and the heterogeneity of impacts, and therefore it will have implications for the interpretation of any impact evaluation. Specificity will be especially important in the case of health insurance evaluation. The impact of insurance in this case on key outcomes of interest, such as health or nutritional status, will be strongly affected by the quality of the health services on offer. In particular, a limited impact of health insurance could be caused by problems with the insurance product (and the incentives regarding health seeking behaviour) or by problems related to the quality of health care it provides access to. As a result, health insurance evaluation is bound to have to be rather different from the evaluation of most other products, especially for those products for whom the impact is mainly dependent on the financial compensation for a loss that is experienced (such as the loss of a crop, property or costs related to mortality).

DOES FURTHER RESEARCH: DOES INSURANCE ENHANCE WELFARE?
The key question deserving more attention relates to the overall impact on household welfare, such as whether persons protected are better able to manage risks and break the poverty cycle than persons without insurance? More research is clearly needed on specific aspects of this, such as (i) To what extent do low-income households adopt more efficient risk-management strategies when they start using microinsurance? (ii) How do consumers use insurance payouts? (iii) Does insurance coverage promote undertaking higher-risk, more productive economic activities? (iv) Does health insurance contribute to more efficient health seeking behaviours? Any of these impacts will need to be unpacked further to address questions such as which segments of low-income households benefit the most? What are the intra-household dynamics? How does insurance impact women, men, other household members? How do they benefit? (e.g. is it through more efficient behaviours, stronger asset or human capital position, more asset accumulation, etc.) Are there any externalities at the community level? For example, does it affect local health care provision, does it crowd out informal schemes, does it affect credit markets? Finally, questions arise about which products provide the highest impact: what is the best product for particular risks in particular circumstances. This can be related to pricing of products (e.g. low premiums with low protection compared to high premium for higher protection)? Or comparing the impact of single versus composite products (for example, combining health and agriculture insurance products, or mandatory versus voluntary products). Product comparison should not limit itself to insurance alone: a key concern when studying the impact of insurance will have to be more work on comparing the impact of insurance with other complementary financial services (such as savings, consumption or emergency credit) as well as safety nets and social protection (including social security and cash transfers). Box 1. Methodological Notes on Impact-Related Research
(a) To study the impact of insurance schemes, it is necessary to design the data collection in such as way that credible counterfactuals can be constructed, meaning that one needs to be able to assess what the impact of insurance is compared to having no insurance. This can be obtained using randomized controlled trials (in which among a population, the ‘beneficiary’ group is randomly chosen in relation to non-beneficiaries), before and after evaluations with control groups (in which control groups are established that can be considered similar to the beneficiaries involved). Alternative designs that could be consistent with these outcomes include quasi-

7
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

experimental designs (for example, ‘natural’ experiments, or the exploitation of staggered introduction of schemes or evaluation exploiting rules of implementation that allow credible counterfactual analysis near the threshold that separates beneficiaries and non-beneficiaries). (b) In quasi-experimental designs care must be taken to account for existing risk coping strategies in the absence of insurance. The question is whether poor people would benefit from insurance relative to these alternatives (often informal institutions with insurance characteristics). An important challenge is to compare the cost of insurance with the (implicit) cost of such alternative arrangements. (c) Researchers are encouraged to take into account that in practice people who choose to take up insurance are likely to differ systematically from others. In experimental designs researchers may therefore want to define the treatment group as those to whom insurance is offered (but may decide not to enrol in the program). (d) Impact assessment of insurance is fundamentally difficult as, by definition, insured losses may not occur for many of the participating households during a relatively short evaluation period. For example, only those experiencing health problems will receive payouts of health insurance. The result is that those paying a premium and not facing losses may seem ‘ex-post’ to be worse off than those not paying a premium, if few people experienced any losses in the period of investigation.

Source: Concept Note prepared by EUDN (2008).

8
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

4 > DEMAND FOR MICROINSURANCE PRODUCTS
Successful microinsurance products need to give careful attention to clients’ demand and satisfaction; often they appear to be more tailored to the providers’ needs. This implies a movement away from products ‘masked’ as microinsurance products but often mainly benefiting MFIs, such as credit-life insurance, towards paying more attention to the insurance needs of the poor. To be able to develop in this direction, it is crucial to obtain a better understanding of why people do or do not take up insurance products when offered: what limits the usage of insurance? Increased demand through well-informed choices of individuals is a prerequisite for scaling up microinsurance products to reach large numbers of poor people. A considerable body of research has been making careful points on these issues, increasingly based on good evidence. Table 4 provides an overview of some of the most relevant demand side issues, and some of the papers that have discussed these issues. It is again important to highlight the peculiarity of health insurance vis-à-vis other other insurance products. The demand for health insurance is not solely a function of product attributes of the insurance, consumer education and appreciation of the insurance product, but also crucially depends on the quality of health care services offered. Table 4. Understanding the demand for insurance? Issues Researchers involved Cohen and Sebstad (2006) Most important riskSebstad et al. (2006) management needs researching demand for microinsurance Churchill (2006) Successful product Leftley and Mapfumo attributes (2006) McCord (2008) Chankova et al. (2008) Factors influencing uptake Gine et al. (2007b)

Evidence - health - loss of income earner - highly context specific, require careful market research - simple - affordable - valuable
- education of household head - wealth - lack of understanding of mechanisms behind insurance - lack of effort by insurance agents to explain products in a way that is understandable for loweducation, illiterate groups - building on existing structures - education - careful marketing and sales strategies - arguments for subsidizing insurance premia for vulnerable groups - nominal willingness to pay is higher than estimated in previous studies - importance of household size as determinant of nominal willingness to pay

Literacy gaps

McCord (2001a) Chankova et al. (2008)

Improving trust and credibility in insurance providers

Radermacher et al. (2006) Schneider (2005) Gilson (2003)

Willingness to pay

Dror et al. (2007)

Cohen and Sebstad (2006) highlight the need to carefully study clients’ insurance needs before introducing a new product, where market research can include studying (i) clients’ needs, (ii) specific products, or (iii) the size of the potential market5. Analyzing demand studies from Uganda, Malawi, Philippines, Vietnam, Indonesia, Lao P.D.R., Georgia, Ukraine and Bolivia they find that the most prevalent risks relate to health and loss of a wage earner. However, despite these patterns, households’ priorities regarding demand for insuring certain risks are nevertheless context specific and solid research is essential before entering a market.
5

See Sebstad et al. (2006) for guidelines on researching demand for microinsurance.

9
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

There seems to be general agreement about the most important product attributes of microinsurance products from a client perspective: simple, affordable and valuable (Churchill, 2006; Leftley and Mapfumo, 2006; McCord, 2008). These factors are determinants of uptake and therefore determine the impact of microinsurance as well. An often identified constraint in selling insurance to poor households is a lack of understanding of insurance products (McCord, 2001a). More educated households have been found to be the ones who are more likely to take up insurance (Chankova et al., 2008; Gine et al., 2007b).6 Overcoming this constraint requires a dual effort to improve communication and financial education on riskpooling, insurance and rights of policy-holders tailored to low-educated and illiterate individuals on the one hand, and simplify policies on the other hand. Clients’ understanding of insurance products is key not only to take up of insurance, but also to use and appreciation of the policy as well as satisfaction with the insurance. The impact of microinsurance on the welfare of the poorest households strongly depends on whether households are aware of the benefits of the insurance, can therefore make full use of it, and continue to stay members of their insurance policy. However, keeping products affordable implies keeping costs low. Therefore, more research is needed on innovative, cost-effective ways and channels of communication and financial education tailored to cater to low-educated, illiterate people.7 A serious constraint to the uptake of insurance has to be trust. The contrast of microinsurance with microcredit helps to see the difference between these two microinsurance activities. In the latter, money is offered first, and then lenders have to find ways of ensuring that clients repay the loan – lenders have to find ways to ensure they can trust that repayment by clients will take place. In insurance, clients first part with their money, and then they have to trust the insurer that they will indeed get money (or a service, such as health care) when problems arise. Lenders have to trust borrowers; while insurers have to be trusted by clients. Radermacher et al. (2006) underline the importance of trust along these two dimensions: first, that the insurer is willing to make payments to clients; and second, that the insurer is able to deliver the payments. Trust is also essential for customer retention. Trust of individuals and communities can be built by education, building on existing structures, or through careful marketing and sales strategies. McCord (2008) underlines that a fine balance is required between acquisition of new technologies (which decrease costs by making the insurance product less labor intense) and human contact to educate policy holders and build trust. Despite its importance, there is little systematic knowledge about instruments and mechanisms to build trust (Schneider, 2005). Dror et al. (2007) study households’ willingness to pay, analyzing data from a bidding game conducted in more than 3000 households in India. They find a higher level of nominal willingness to pay compared to previous studies; further, they show that household income and nominal willingness to pay are positively correlated, while household income and willingness to pay as a percentage of household income is negatively correlated. Further, their results suggest that household size is the most important determinant of willingness to pay levels. Willingness to pay could also be enhanced by simplifying premium collection methods and making premiums payable in higher frequencies could be helpful in promoting enrolment by low-income households (Chankova, 2008). Paying premiums should be in line with households’ cash flows (Cohen and Sebstad, 2006).

This problem should not come as a surprise: even basic concepts of risk and insurance tend to be poorly understood in many poor settings (Platteau, 1997). 7 This problem is not just a problem of a poor understanding of formal insurance. Even the mere concepts of risk and of the principles of insurance, even in informal settings, are difficult to grasp. Platteau (1998) documents how fishing communities, despite facing clear risk, find it hard to understand fully the principles of insurance, including that they are not just ‘savings’ schemes so that premiums have to be returned ‘in due course’, and not just in probability.

6

10
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

RESEARCH: FURTHER RESEARCH: THE DEMAND FOR INSURANCE?
There clearly is a need for more and careful analysis of the demand for insurance. The key is to offer products to clients that really offer value to clients, and understanding clients, their needs and their satisfaction with products is essential. At least as important is to understand whether and how clients can be retained. The key questions to understand are therefore (i) why people buy or don’t buy insurance products when offered, and (ii) why do people not renew their insurance? At the end of this section, box 2 offers some methodological guidance useful when addressing some of these questions. A first sub-set of questions addresses this issue of ‘client-value’ – what is offered to clients and how satisfied are they with these products. Obviously, any research has to be closely linked to questions discussed in the previous section, related to the actual impact on welfare outcomes, but here, the actual outcomes are not only important, but the focus here is more on the insurance product itself, focusing on the uptake and satisfaction of clients. Specific questions include: To what extent are clients satisfied with current microinsurance products? What do they value? What product attributes are the most important for them and why? What is the potential benefit or the actual client value of different microinsurance products for different groups in different contexts? For which risks and for whom can microinsurance provide better value in terms of appropriateness (demanded protection coverage), affordability (total costs) and accessibility (simplicity, physical access, convenience) compared to or in combination with other riskmanagement mechanisms (including credit, savings, insurance, informal schemes, safety nets, social security) used to date? What are access frontiers for different types of risks/products? How deep can a marketbased insurance scheme reach? To what extent can microinsurance enhance value of basic social security packages (health care, maternity, pensions, unemployment benefits) for low-income households? Besides these questions, analysis of demand, uptake and retention have to dig deeper into the market conditions and constraints to insurance provision. A key concern has to be an understanding of the potential market, to provide the necessary market intelligence to penetrate low-income markets. What is the size of the potential market in specific contexts and expected take up rate? Is there scope for market segmentation to assist penetration and increased understanding of markets? There are also the key issues related to insurance understanding and literacy, and trust in insurance provision and providers. Relevant questions include: Why do consumers not trust insurance, insurance providers and system? How to build trust? How do households understand risk? Do they properly understand insurance concepts, for example as distinct from pooled savings? How are they understood in different cultural settings? What are the most important gaps in insurance literacy - knowledge (understanding of concepts), skills (being able to use insurance for effective risk-management), and attitudes (opinions, culture and self-confidence)? Finally, insurance does not tend to be offered for free to be sustainable or to offer appropriate incentives. Questions requiring more answers include: How sensitive are potential clients to price changes? How much can different households be expected to be able to contribute to insurance? Box 2. Methodological Notes on Demand-Related Research
For many of these questions, the variable of interest is the uptake of insurance. To allow a clear understanding of many of these issues, such as related to the link between price or other product attributes, a well-defined ‘counterfactual’ remains necessary, so that the comments above on impact analysis remain relevant. (As noted above, the counterfactual may involve participation in an informal institution (social insurance) or the use of livestock or other assets for self-insurance.) Similarly, for studies related to finding schemes that appear to have more credibility (e.g. schemes with more frequent interaction in the form of small payouts), the key tools for analysis are likely to be similar (i.e. making a comparison between different schemes, with well defined control groups). The same applies to studying the impact of information programmes on uptake. However, there is room for other methods as well. The design issues related to developing credibility require further conceptual and theoretical work, while documenting cases in a comparative framework remains relevant. A study of the understanding of risk and of insurance may well have to go beyond standard economic, business

11
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

or insurance analysis into the realm of psychology or anthropology. The study of insurance behaviour is often done using willingness to pay or other hypothetical questioning. Caution is required as the relationship between actual insurance behaviour (such as subsequent uptake) and responses to willingness to pay is typically not strong. Experimental games may offer some insight but issues such as the longterm horizon of actual insurance relationships (with payouts often many years later if any) make the replication of actual circumstances relatively implausible in short game settings. In any case, revealed risk aversion and actual uptake of insurance are substantively different concepts, partly motivating the type of research proposed.

Source: Concept Note prepared by EUDN (2008).

12
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

5 > SUPPLY
Two key issues deserve specific attention when considering the research on the supply of microinsurance products. First, developing and pricing microinsurance products and secondly, the relevant institutional models and delivery channels. Table 5 presents an overview of selected studies. Table 5. Key challenges and bottlenecks for widespread and sustainable provision? Issues Researchers involved Key Conclusions
Brown and Churchill (2000a) Wipf et al. (2006) Leftley and Mapfumo (2006) Wipf and Garand (2006) McCord et al. (2006) Churchill and Cohen (2006) McCord (2000a; 2000b; 2000c 2001a; 20001b, 2006; 2008) Fischer and Qureshi (2006) Leftley and Roth (2006) Radermacher and Dror (2006) Detailed suggestions on balancing inclusion, premiums, benefits and sustainability; need for professionalisation for pricing: involvement of insurance professionals.

Developing and pricing microinsurance products

Institutional models and delivery channels

Arguments on agnosticism regarding institutional models is required; issues related to incentive contracts for agents

The first step in the design of an insurance product should be evaluating the insurability of the risks the product is intended to cover. Brown and Churchill (2000a) discuss a number of criteria, which include (i) a large number of similar units exposed to risk, (ii) limited policyholder control over the insured event, (iii) the existence of insurable interest, (iv) losses can be identified and measured, (v) losses should not be catastrophic, (vi) chance of loss is calculable and (vii) premiums are economically affordable. Leftley and Mapfumo (2006) highlight the importance of a focus on the demand side for developing a successful product, coupled with an iterating process of examining the operational and regulatory environment as well as risk carrier options. Insurers always have to strike a balance between inclusion, premiums, policy coverage and financial sustainability. The CHAT tool, developed by the Micro Insurance Academy, deals with the coverage-premium tradeoff by providing a menu of choices and letting clients chose their desired coverage and corresponding premium (Dror, 2007). Composite (bundled) insurance products, as recommended by Cohen and McGuinness in McCord (2008), can be useful instruments to manage moral hazard and adverse selection problems and thus offer cheaper products. Nevertheless, Roth and Chamberlain (2006) warn that in practice the potential benefit of bundled microinsurance in terms of lower premiums is hardly passed on to clients.

DELIVERY INSTITUTIONAL MODELS AND DELIVERY CHANNELS
McCord (2001a) contrasts four classical service delivery models: the partner-agent model, community based model, the full-service model, and the provider model. In the partner-agent model, the insurer teams up with a local agent, for example, a microfinance institution, informal savings institution or other grass-root organizations. For example, in Uganda, FINCA Uganda cooperated with Nsambya Hospital Healthcare Plan (NHHP), a health financing entity, to provide health insurance to its clients (McCord, 2000a). Under this setup, the comparative advantage of the insurer in developing and pricing policies is combined with the comparative advantage of the local agent by having

13
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

experience in reaching the poor, with networks already in place, and enjoying the trust of large numbers of clients. However, McCord (2006) also discusses a number of disadvantages for insurers, agents and clients. For the partner-agent model to work for the poor, he stresses that (i) the insurance product and distribution has to be driven by clients’ needs, (ii) the regulatory framework should facilitate simple procedures while at the same time protecting customers’ rights, and (iii) MFIs should involve clients in product development and obtain feed-back, to use this information in negotiations with the insurer. In India, Tata-AIG has developed a model of micro-agents in addition to MFIs as agents. NGOs are contracted to recommend individuals in communities to form a so-called community rural insurance group (CRIG) which then performs an agent’s role (Roth and Athreye, 2005). In the community-based model the insurance is entirely owned and managed by the community members (the policy holders). It is not-for-profit, and characterized by its participatory processes and the important role of social cohesion. Community-based insurances, or mutual insurances, can be found in a variety of setups, including: (i) standalone mutual (or cooperative) insurance providers (for example, CARD MBA in the Philippines), (ii) insurance companies affiliated to a network of financial cooperatives such as savings and credit cooperatives (for example, MUSCCO in Malawi and ServiPeru in Peru) and (iii) networks of mutual insurance associations (for example, the Union Technique de la Mutualité Malienne) (Fischer and Qureshi, 2006). Under the full-service model, the insurance provider assumes all functions, from product development to marketing, sales, premium collection and claims processing. An example for the full-service model is the SelfEmployed Women’s Association Insurance (SEWA) in India. Extending this model to also include the provision of, for example, health care, yields the provider model. GRET Cambodia is an example of a health microinsurance following the provider model (McCord, 2001b). Leftley and Roth (2006) discuss alternative institutional approaches, including the use of a protected cell company, alternative administrative procedures such as amended agency agreements, or outsourcing to third party administrators, as well as alternative distribution channels, such as retailers, workers’ unions, cell phone companies, or burial societies and ROSCAs. In conclusion, many of the above discussed models are under development and ‘agnosticism about insurance models’ (McCord, 2008) is needed to establish the most effective delivery channels for different risk categories. Further knowledge is also required regarding effective marketing and selling, and underlying incentive contracts of agents. Francis Sommerwell, managing director of microcare (in McCord, 2008) points out the importance of costumer retention for building trust and for an insurance to function. To provide adequate incentives, agents get higher commission for renewals than new sales.

FURTHER RESEARCH
Key indicators for supply analysis are efficiency and outreach. A massive research agenda is still outstanding, as much learning will have to be done based on actual experiences, focusing on the supply value chain, but also conceptually and theoretically. The main question is: How to expand access to valuable products in an efficient way? The questions below are structured around supply value chain concerns, which is key from the practitioners’ point of view; delivery models and linkages; pricing issues and the supply of consumer education. Questions around the supply value chain are: How can providers improve efficiency of business processes to expand access to valuable products? Why certain processes and solutions in the supply value chain presented below work and why some do not work? What are costs in the value chain and how they can

14
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

be trimmed? This is a broad area, covering issues such as getting the products right, organising efficient distribution systems, including the delivery channels, the appropriate bundling with other insurance financial and non-financial products, sales and management models, etc. Further questions include: How can technology help to improve efficiencies in the supply value chain? What are the costs and benefits of various technological solutions? Next, one needs more research on possible delivery models: Which delivery models work best in specific contexts in terms of insurance uptake, sustainability and efficiency for providers, and the highest client value? What are cost-effective linkages between market-based microinsurance and informal schemes or social security schemes? Pricing insurance is also crucial. Research questions include: How can providers overcome data limitations for actuarial pricing? What is the rationale and role of subsidies? What are the potential detrimental effects on efficiency? Finally, if trust and literacy are crucial constraints on the demand, the content of consumer education as well as its delivery require more research. How should it be organised? Who should do it – independent groups or insurers? What should be addressed? Box 3 below offers some generic methodological issues when researching these questions. Of course, different products dealing with different risks face different supply side problems, leading to specific other questions to be addressed. In box 4, as an example, some of these more specific questions are articulated for the contrasting issues related to health insurance delivery and agricultural insurance delivery. Box 3. Methodological Notes on Supply-Related Research
For many of these questions, the variable of interest is not easily defined, as it refers to the efficiency or sustainability of microinsurance operations. The need for well-defined ‘counterfactuals’ remains necessary. For some issues, such as comparing different models of delivery (e.g. individual versus group based), the principles and methods of impact analysis as discussed earlier would still be most relevant. For others, the evidence base will be hard to construct (such as comparative empirical work on institutional models, which rarely operate in comparable contexts). By implication, much of the work will have to be based on careful theoretical/conceptual work, supplemented with carefully documented case studies to offer empirical evidence. The virtues of theoretical analysis (such as on delivery models), should not be underestimated, even if based on rather stylised differences. In general, this work will have to be done in the context of a limited information base, and efforts to build this information base in a systematic and, if possible, quantitative way should be strongly encouraged.

Source: Concept Note prepared by EUDN (2008).

15
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Box 4: Specific questions for health and agricultural insurance
Further questions for health insurance delivery How to limit adverse selection for both comprehensive indemnity packages and defined benefit schemes? What is the best use of co-payments and deductibles to limit moral hazard without undermining demand for products and discouraging clients from seeking preventive health care? What is the impact of exclusions on performance and client value? What are good practices to finance and collect premiums cost effectively? How to reimburse health providers directly so that claims are cashless for policyholders? How to reduce health claims costs, including prevention and negotiations with health care and pharmaceutical providers? How to control the risk of fraud? How can health insurers encourage greater use of, and improvements to, public health or government health care services? What is the role of technology and Third Party Administrators in increasing efficiencies of the health insurance supply chain? What is the right reinsurance mechanism for health insurance? Further questions for weather index and other agriculture insurance specifics How to build weather and other indexes to create transparent and efficient index insurance products? What are relevant triggers for crop products? How to reduce basis risk? What is the sufficient level of correlation between bad weather and bad crop yields? How to overcome the lack of historic weather data? What is the impact of climate change on the usefulness of historic data? What is necessary weather infrastructure to collect the right data for index insurance? To what extent local communities can be involved in designing weather maps? How to market index insurance products, ensure transparency and understanding by the market? What is the impact of disaster relief or food aid on the market for index insurance? Can index insurance be extended beyond farmers to ensure its sustainability and share its benefits with other groups? What are proper reserves and reinsurance policies needed for index insurance? How to reduce fraud and moral hazard in delivering livestock insurance? What is feasibility of other property insurance products for agriculture?

16
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

BIBLIOGRAPHY
Ahmed, M..U., Islam, S.K., Quashem, M. and Ahmed, N. (2005), Health Microinsurance: A comparative study of the Three Examples in Bangladesh, CGAP Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 13 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Alderman, H., Hoddinott, J. and B. Kinsey, J. (2006), Long-term consequences of early childhood malnutrition, Oxford Economic Papers, 58: 450-474. Almeyda, G. and de Paula Jaramillo, F. (2005). La Equidad Seguros, Colombia, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 12 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Attanasio, O. and Rios-Rull, J.V. (2000). Consumption smoothing in island economies: can public insurance reduce welfare? European Economic Review, 44(7), 1225-1258. Banerjee, A. (2005). The Two Poverties, in S. Dercon (ed.), Insurance Against Poverty, Oxford University Press. Bennett, S., Creese, A. and Monasch, R. (1998). Health Insurance Schemes for People Outside Formal Sector Employment, World Health Organization, Geneva, Switzerland. Bie Lilleor, H., X.Gine, R.M.Townsend and J.Vickery (2005). Weather Insurance in Semi-Arid India. Bigsten, A., Collier, P., Dercon, S., Fafchamps, M., Gauthier, B., Gunning, J.W., Oduro, A., Oostendorp, R., Pattillo, C., Soderbom, M., Teal, F. and Zeufack, A. (2003). Risk Sharing in Labour Markets, World Bank Economic Review, 17(3):349-366. Brown, W. and Churchill, C.F. (2000a). Insurance Provision in Low Income Communities. Part I: A primer on insurance principles and products, USAID – Microenterprise Best Practices (MBP) Project. Brown, W. and Churchill, C.F. (2000b). Insurance Provision in Low Income Communities. Part II: Initial Lessons from Micro-Insurance Experiments for the Poor, USAID – Microenterprise Best Practices (MBP) Project. Chankova, S., Sulzbach, S. and Diop, F. (2008). Impact of mutual health organizations: evidence from West Africa, Health Policy and Planning, 23(4):264-276. Chatterjee, M. (2005). Microinsurance – a note on the State of the Art. Note on workshops organized by SEWA in September 2003 and September 2004. Chou, S.-Y., Liu, J.-T. and Hammitt, J.K. (2003). National Health Insurance and Precautionary Saving: Evidence from Taiwan, Journal of Public Economics, 87(9-10): 1873-94. Churchill, C. (2006). What is insurance for the poor? in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Churchill, C. and Cohen, M. (2006). Marketing Microinsurance, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Churchill, C. and Pepler, T. (2004). TUW SKOK, Poland, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 2 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Cohen, M. and Sebstad, J. (2006). The demand for microinsurance, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Deaton, A. (1997). The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, Maryland. Dercon, S. (1996). Risk, Crop Choice and Savings: Evidence from Tanzania, Economic Development and Cultural Change, 44(3): 385-514. Dercon, S. (2005). Risk, Insurance and Poverty: A Review, in S. Dercon (ed.), Insurance against Poverty, Oxford University Press.

17
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Dercon, S. (2008). Risk, Poverty, and Human Development: what do we know, what do we need to know?, background paper to the Human Development Report 2008. Dercon, S. and Christiaensen, L. (2007). Consumption risk, technology adoption and poverty traps: evidence from Ethiopia, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4257. Dercon, S. and Hoddinott, J. (2005). Health, Shocks and Poverty Persistence, in S. Dercon (ed.), Insurance against Poverty, Oxford University Press. Dercon, S. and Krishnan, P. (2003). Risk Sharing and Public Transfers, Economic Journal, 113(486): C86-C94. Dong, H., Bogg, L., Wang, K., Rehnberg, C., Diwan V. (1999). A description of outpatient drug use in rural China: Evidence of differences due to insurance coverage, International Journal of Health Planning and Management, 14: 41–56. Dror, I. (2007). Demystifying Micro Health Insurance Package Design - Choosing Healthplans All Together (Chat), Microfinance Insights, 4:17-19. Dror D.M., Radermacher, R. and Koren, R.(2007). Willingness to Pay for Health Insurance Among Rural and Poor Persons: Field Evidence from Seven Micro Health Insurance Units in India, Health Policy, (82):1. Dror, D. M., Koren, R., and Steinberg, D.M. (2006). The Impact of Filipino Micro Health Insurance Units on IncomeRelated Equality of Access to Healthcare, Health Policy, 77(3): 304–317. Ekman, B. (2004). Community-based health insurance in low-income countries: a systematic review of the evidence, Health Policy and Planning, 19: 249–70. Elbers, C., Gunning, J.W. and Kinsey, B. (2007). Growth and Risk: Methodology and Micro-evidence, World Bank Economic Review, 21(1): 1-20. Elbers, C., J.W. Gunning and L. Pan (2008), Insurance and rural welfare: what can panel data tell us, Applied Economics, published on line. Enarsson, S. and Wirén, K. (2005). MUSCCO, Malawi Union of Savings and Credit Cooperatives, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 8 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Enarsson, S. and Wirén, K. (2006). ALMAO and YASIRU, Sri Lanka, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 21 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Fafchamps, M., Gunning, J.W. and Oostendorp, R. (2000). Inventories and Risk in African Manufacturing, Economic Journal, 110(466): 861-893. Fischer, K.., Hathie, I. and Sissouma, I. (2006a). Mutual health insurance, CRMST, Senegal, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 24 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Fischer, K., Sissouma, I. and Hathie, I. (2006b). L’Union Technique de la Mutualité Malienne, Mali, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 23 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Fischer, K., and Qureshi, Z. (2006). Cooperatives and insurance: The mutual advantage, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Garand, D. (2005). VimoSEWA, India, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 16 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Gautier, B., Boutbien, A. and Galland, B. (2005). L’Union des Mutuelles de Santé de Guinée Forestière, Guinea, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 17 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Gertler, P. and Gruber, J. (2002). Insuring Consumption against Illness, American Economic Review, 92(1), 51-76.

18
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Gilson, L. (2003). Trust and development of health care as a social institution. Social Science & Medicine, 56, 1453–1468. Gine, X., Townsend, R.M. and Vickery, J. (2007a). Statistical Analysis of Rainfall Insurance Payouts in Southern India, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 89(5): 1248-1254. Gine, X., Townsend, R.M. and Vickery, J. (2007b). Patterns of Rainfall Insurance Participation in Rural India, Policy Research Working Paper Series 4408, The World Bank. Gine, X., and Yang, D. (2007). Insurance, Credit, and Technology Adoption: Field Experimental Evidence from Malawi, Policy Research Working Paper Series 4425, The World Bank. Gruber, J. and Yelowitz, A. (1999). Public Health Insurance and Private Savings, Journal of Political Economy, 107(6): 1249-74. Guérin, O. (2006). Association d’Entraide des Femmes, Benin, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 22 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Gumber, A. (2001). Hedging the Health of the Poor: The Case for Community Financing in India. Health, Nutrition and Population Discussion Paper, World Bank, Washington DC. Herrera, C. and Miranda, B. (2004). Columna, Guatemala, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 5 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Hoddinott, J. and Kinsey, B. (2001). Child growth in a time of drought, Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 63: 409-436. Holst, J. (2005). Health microinsurance: A comparison of four publicly run schemes, Latin America, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 18 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). International Cooperative and Mutual Insurance Federation (ICMIF). (2005). Lessons learnt the hard way, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 6 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Jain, Shashi. 1999. Basic Social Security in India, in Wouter van Ginneken (ed.), Social Security for the Excluded Majority: Case Studies from Developing Countries. International Labor Organization, Geneva, Switzerland. Jowett, M. (2003). Do informal risk sharing networks crowd out public voluntary health Insurance? Evidence from Vietnam, Applied Economics, 35: 1153–1161. Jowett M., Contoyannis P., Vinh N.D. (2003). The impact of public voluntary health insurance on private health expenditures in Vietnam, Social Science and Medicine, 56: 333–342. Jütting, J. (2004). Do community-based health insurance schemes improve poor people’s access to health care? Evidence from rural Senegal, World Development, 32: 273–88. Leftley, R. (2005). Technical assistance for the promotion of microinsurance: The experience of Opportunity International, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 11 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Leftley, R. and Mapfumo, S. (2006). Effective microinsurance programs to reduce vulnerability. Opportunity International Network. Leftley, R. and Roth, J. (2006). Beyond MFIs and community-based models: Institutional alternatives, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Lybbert, T.J., C.B. Barrett, S. Desta and D.L. Coppock (2004), Stochastic wealth dynamics and risk management among a poor population, Economic Journal, 114: 750-777.

19
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Manje, L. (2005). Madison Insurance, Zambia, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No.10 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). McCord, M.J. (2000a). Microinsurance in Uganda: a case study of an example of the partner-agent model of microinsurance provision – AIG/FINCA Uganda – group personal accident insurance, Nairobi: MicroSave-Africa. McCord, M.J. (2000b). Microinsurance in Uganda: a case study of an example of the partner-agent model of microinsurance provision - NHHP/FINCA Uganda – Heath Care Financing Plan, Nairobi: MicroSave-Africa. McCord, M.J. (2000c). Microinsurance: A Case Study of an Example of the Mutual Model of Microinsurance Provision: UMASIDA, Nairobi: MicroSave-Africa. McCord, M.J. (2001a). Health care microinsurance - case studies from Uganda, Tanzania, India and Cambodia, Small Enterprise Development, 12(1): 25-38. McCord, M.J. (2001b). Microinsurance: A Case Study of an Example of the Provider Model of Microinsurance Provision: Gret Cambodia. MicroSave, Nairobi. McCord, M.J. (2006). The Partner-Agent Model: Challenges and Opportunities, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. McCord, M.J. and Churchill, C. (2005). Delta Life, Bangladesh, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 7 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). McCord, M.J, Botero, F., and McCord, J.S. (2005). AIG Uganda: A member of the American International Group of Companies, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 9 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). McCord, M.J. and Buczkowski, G. (2004). CARD MBA, The Philippines, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 4 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). McCord, M.J., Buczkowski, G., and Saksena, P. (2006). Premium collection: Minimizing transaction costs and maximizing customer service, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. McCord, M.J., Isern, J., and Hashemi, S. (2001). Microinsurance: A Case Study Example of the Full Service Model of Microinsurance Provision, Self-Employed Women’s Associations. MicroSave-Africa. McCord, M.J. (2008). Visions of the future of Microinsurance, and thoughts on getting there, Microinsurance note no. 9, United States Agency for International Development. Morduch, J. (1990). Risk, Production and Saving: Theory and Evidence from Indian Households, Harvard University, Manuscript. Morduch, J. (1995). Income Smoothing and Consumption Smoothing, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(3):103114. Morduch, J. (1999). Between the State and the Market: Can Informal Insurance Patch the Safety Net?, World Bank Research Observer, 14(2):187-207. Morduch, J. (2006). Microinsurance: the next revolution? in A.V. Banerjee, R. Benabou and D. Mookherjee (eds.), Understanding Poverty, Oxford University Press. Musau, S. (1999). Community-Based Health Insurance: Experiences and Lessons Learned from East and Southern Africa, Technical Report No. 34. Bethesda, MD: Partnerships fro Health Reform Project, Abt Associates Inc. Pan, L., 2008, Poverty, Risk and Insurance: Evidence from Ethiopia and Yemen, unpublished PhD thesis, VU University Amsterdam. Platteau, J.P. (1997), Mutual Insurance as an Elusive Concept in Traditional Rural Societies, Journal of Development Studies, 33 (6): 764-96.

20
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Preker, A.S., Carrin, G., Dror, D.M., Jakab, M., Hsiao, W. and Arhin, D. (2002). Effectiveness of Community Health Financing in Meeting the Cost of Illness, Bulletin of the World Health Organization, 80(2): 143-150. Preker, A.S. (2007). The Evolution of Health Insurance in Developing Countries, in Alexander S. Preker, Richard M. Scheffler and Mark C. Bassett (eds.), Private Volunatary Health Insurance in Development: Friend or Foe?, Washington D.C.: The World Bank. Radermacher, R. and Dror, I. (2006). Institutional options for delivering health microinsurance, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Radermacher, R., van Putten-Rademacher, O., Müller, V., Wig, N. and Dror, D. (2005a). Karuna Trust, Karnataka, India, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 19 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Radermacher, R., van Putten-Rademacher, O., Müller, V., Wig, N. and Dror, D. (2005b). Yeshasvini Trust, Karnataka - India, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 20 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Radermacher, R., Dror, I., and Noble, G. (2006). Challenges and strategies to extend health insurance to the poor, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Ranson, K.M. (2001). The impact of SEWA’s Medical Insurance Fund on Hospital Utilization and Expenditure: A Household Survey. Health, Nutrition and Population Discussion Paper, World Bank, Washington DC. Ranson, K. M. (2004). The SEWA Medical Insurance Fund in India, in A. Preker and G. Carrin (ed.), Health Financing for Poor People: Resource Mobilization and Risk Sharing. World Bank, Washington D.C. Rodríguez, M. and Miranda, B. (2004). ServiPerú, Peru, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 1 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Rosenzweig, M. and Binswanger, H. (1990). Productivity, health and inequality in the intrahousehold distribution of food in low income countries. American Economic Review, 80:1139-1156. Rosenzweig, M. and Binswanger, H. (1993). Wealth, Weather Risk and the Composition and Profitability of Agricultural Investments, Economic Journal, 103:56-78. Rosenzweig, M.R. and Wolpin, K. (1993), Credit market constraints, consumption smoothing, and the accumulation of durable production assets in low-income countries: investment in bullocks in India, Journal of Political Economy, 101: 223-244. Roth, J. and Athreye, V. (2005). TATA-AIG Life Insurance Company Ltd., India, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 14 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Roth, J. and Chamberlain, D. (2006). Retailers as microinsurance distribution channels, in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Roth, J., Churchill, C., Ramm, G. and Namerta. (2005). Microinsurance and microfinance institutions: Evidence from India, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 15 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Schneider, P. (2005). Trust in micro-health insurance: an exploratory study in Rwanda. Social Science and Medicine, 61:1430-38. Sebstad, J., Cohen, M. and McGuinness, E. (2006). Guidelines for market research on the demand for microinsurance, microREPORT #69, United States Agency for International Development. Sen, A.K. (1981). Poverty and famines: An Essay on Entitlement and Deprivation, Oxford: Clarendon Press New York.

21
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Sriram, M.S. (2005). Expanding Financial Services Access for the Poor: The Transformation of SPANDANA, IIMA Working Paper 2005-04-03, Indian Institute of Management Ahmedabad. Svensson, J. (2003). Who Must Pay Bribes and How Much? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1): 207-30. Townsend, R.M. (1995). Consumption Insurance: An Evaluation of Risk-Bearing Systems in Low-Income Economies, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 9(3):83-102. Tran, N. and Yun, T. S. (2004). TYM’s Mutual Assistance Fund, Viet Nam, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 3 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Tremblay, C., Quirion, M., Langlois, S., and Klutzé, F. (2006). MAFUCECTO, Togo, CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, Good and Bad Practices Case Study No. 25 (Geneva, ILO Social Finance Programme). Wagstaff, A. (2007). Health Insurance for the Poor: Initial Impacts of Vietnam’s Health Care Fund for the Poor, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4134. The World Bank. Wagstaff, A., Lindelow, M., Jun, G., Ling, X and Juncheng, Q. (2007). Extending Health Insurance to the Rural Population: An Impact Evaluation of China’s New Cooperative Medical Scheme, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4150. The World Bank. Wagstaff, A. (2008). Measures for Financial Protection in Health, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 4554. The World Bank. Wagstaff, A. and Pradhan, M. (2005): Health Insurance Impacts on Health and Nonmedical Consumption in a Developing Country, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3563. The World Bank. Wipf, J., and Garand, D. (2006). Pricing Microinsurance Products. in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. Wipf, J., and Liber, D., and Churchill, C. (2006). Product design and insurance risk management. in C. Churchill (ed.), Protecting the poor, A microinsurance compendium, International Labor Organisation, Geneva. World Bank. (2005). Mongolia Livestock Insurance Project. Project Appraisal Document. May 2, 2005. Young, P., Kiyaga, E. and Mukwana, P. (2006): Microinsurance: Exploring Ways to Asses Its Impact. Microfinance Opportunities.

22
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

ANNEX : OVERVIEW OF SELECTED MICRO INSURANCE PROGRAMMES
Insurer
Activists for Social Alternatives (ASA) All Lanka Mutual Insurance Organization (ALMAO) American International Group (AIG) Uganda/ Foundation for International Community Assistance (FINCA) Uganda Association d’Entraide des Femmes (AssEF) Bangladeshi Rural Advancement Committee (BRAC) Bienestar Magisterial (BM) Center for Agriculture and Rural Development Mutual Benefit Association (CARD MBA) Chogoria Hospital Insurance Scheme Christian Enterprise Trust Zambia (CETZAM) Columna Coordination régionale de mutuelles de santé de Thiès (CRMST) Delta Life Government of Mongolia Grameen Kalyan (GK) Groupe de Recherche et d’Echanges Technologiques (GRET) ICICI Lombard/ BASIX Insurance Association of Malawi International Cooperative and Mutual Insurance Federation (ICMIF) Karuna Trust La Equidad Seguros

Location and Start
India, 1986 Sri Lanka, 2002 life

Current Area of Insurance

References
Roth et al. (2005) Enarsson and Wirén (2006)

life, accident, loan protection

Uganda, 1997

group personal accident insurance

McCord (2000a) McCord et al. (2005) Young et al. (2006)

Benin, 2003 Bangladesh, 2001 El Salvador, 1969

health health health

Guérin (2006) Ahmed et al (2005) Holst (2005) McCord and Buczkowski (2004)

Philippines, 1999

life, credit life, disability

Kenya, 1991 Zambia, 1995 Guatemala, 1993

health credit life, funeral, property credit life, life savings, auto, fire and allied perils, theft health endowment index-based livestock insurance health health

Musau (1999) Leftley (2005) Herrera and Miranda (2004) Fischer et al. (2006a) Chankova et al. (2008) McCord and Churchill (2005) World Bank (2005) Ahmed et al. (2005) McCord (2001b) Brown and Churchill (2000b) Bie Lilleor et al. (2005) Gine et al. (2007a) Gine et al. (2007b) Gine and Yang (2007) International Cooperative and Mutual Insurance Federation (ICMIF) (2005) Radermacher et al. (2005a) Almeyda and Jaramillo

Senegal Bangladesh, 1986 Mongolia Bangladesh, 1997 Cambodia, 1998

India, 2003 Malawi Members in 67 countries, founded in 1992 India, 1987 Colombia, 1970

weather-based insurance weather-based insurance reinsurance, development, market intelligence, investment, training health life, disability

23
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

Insurer

Location and Start

Current Area of Insurance
(2005) credit life, funeral

References

Madison Insurance Malawi Union of Savings and Credit Cooperatives (MUSCCO) Mutuelle d’assurance de la FUCEC-Togo (MAFUCECTO) Nnsambya Hospital Healthcare Plan (NHHP)/FINCA Uganda Seguro Basico de Salud (SBS) Seguro Integral (SI) Seguro Materno-Infantil (SMI) Self Help Promotion for Health and Rural Development (SHEPHERD) ServiPerú Society for Social Services (SSS) Spandana Tao Yeu May’s Mutual Assistance Fund (TYM) Tata-AIG Life Insurance Company Ltd. Taytay Sa Kauswagan (TSKI) TUW SKOK UMASIDA Union des Mutuelles de Santé de Guinée Forestière (UMSGF) Union Technique de la Mutualité Malienne (UTM) VimoSEWA (SEWA- SelfEmployed Women’s Association Insurance) Yasiru Mutual Provident Fund (Yasiru) Yeshasvini Trust

Zambia, 2000 Malawi, 1980

Manje (2005) Enarsson and Wirén (2005) Tremblay et al. (2006)

credit life, life savings credit life

Togo, 1989

Uganda, 1999 Bolivia, 1999 Paraguay, 2002 Peru, 1998

health health health health life, health, accidental death, livestock, asset life, credit life, health, savings, funeral, motor health credit life, spouse’s death, asset credit life, health, disability, funeral life life, credit life accidental death and disability, property, savings completion health health

McCord (2000b) Holst (2005) Holst (2005) Holst (2005)

India, 1995

Roth et al. (2005) Rodríguez and Miranda (2004) Ahmed et al. (2005) Roth et al. (2005) Sriram (2005) Tran and Yun (2004) Roth and Athreye (2005) Leftley (2005) Churchill and Pepler (2004) McCord (2000c) Gautier et al. (2005)

Peru, 1994 Bangladesh, 1993 India, 1992 Vietnam, 1993 India, 2000 Philippines, 1986 Poland, 1998 Tanzania, 1997 Guinea, 1999

Mali, 1998

health

Fischer et al. (2006b) Chatterjee (2005) Ranson (2004) Bennett et al (1998) Jain (1999) Garand (2005) McCord et al. (2001) Enarsson and Wirén (2006) Radermacher et al. (2006)

India, 1992

life, health, accident, property

Sri Lanka, 2000 India, 2003

life, accident, disability, hospitalization health

24
LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

INNOVATION MICROINSURANCE INNOVATION FACILITY
Backed by a grant from the Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, the ILO’s Microinsurance Innovation Facility was established in 2008 to support the extension of insurance to millions of low-income people in the developing world, with the overall aim of reducing their vulnerability to risk. The ultimate objective of the Facility is to encourage the development of microinsurance so that – by the end of 2012 –150 million low-income people will be able to make informed choices on how to manage risk and will have access to a wider range of insurance products that provide better value for money. To achieve its goals, the Facility engages in four sets of activities: o o o o giving grants to institutions to devise and test innovative approaches to providing better insurance products to low-income women and men in developing countries supporting the development of technical assistance providers and encouraging the demand for such services supporting research on core issues related to insurance cover for low-income households disseminating information and lessons learned to key stakeholders

For more information, check the Facility’s website (www.ilo.org/microinsurance) or contact us at microinsuranceresearch@ilo.org .

LITERATURE REVIEW ON MICROINSURANCE

References: Manje (2005) Enarsson and Wirén (2005) Tremblay et al. (2006) credit life, life savings credit life Togo, 1989 Uganda, 1999 Bolivia, 1999 Paraguay, 2002 Peru, 1998 India, 1995 Roth et al Peru, 1994 Bangladesh, 1993 India, 1992 Vietnam, 1993 India, 2000 Philippines, 1986 Poland, 1998 Tanzania, 1997 Guinea, 1999 Mali, 1998 India, 1992 life, health, accident, property Sri Lanka, 2000 India, 2003 life, accident, disability, hospitalization health

You May Also Find These Documents Helpful

  • Powerful Essays

    Hadden WC, Muntaner C, Benach J, Gimeno D, Benavides FG. 2007. A glossary for the social epidemiology of work organisation: Part 3, Terms from the sociology of labour markets. Journal of Epidemiology and Community Health 61(1): 6-8.…

    • 12784 Words
    • 52 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    Labour Relation

    • 3801 Words
    • 16 Pages

    Woodhall, J., & Leach, B. (2010). Retrieved 10 8, 2012, from Just Labour - A Canadian Journal of Work and Society: http://www.justlabour.yorku.ca/volume16/pdfs/05_woodhall_leach_press.pdf…

    • 3801 Words
    • 16 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Better Essays

    Congo -Mozambique -Turkey -East Timor -Nepal -Uganda…

    • 1324 Words
    • 6 Pages
    Better Essays
  • Good Essays

    Is there any evidence that management’s bonuses caused it to enter into any transactions, especially at year-end, that may not have been in the shareholder’s interest?…

    • 1470 Words
    • 6 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Satisfactory Essays

    Moreover, another predominant factor as to why the state should remain to have a role in employment relations, and so businesses can’t set their own terms and conditions of work for their employees, is because there is a significant exploitation of temporary migrant workers and their entitlements. Migrant workers are mistreated in multiple ways for their efforts as an employee. These can encompass of no workers compensation if they were injured in hazardous working conditions and also unsatisfactory or limited pay and entitlements for their efforts, which is due a lack of knowledge of legislations and their rights as employees. As a result of this, exploited migrant workers do not stand up for their rights in the workplace for fear that their employers will retaliate by notifying the police or immigration, resulting in deportation.…

    • 311 Words
    • 2 Pages
    Satisfactory Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    Geneva, international Labour Office -. Global Employement Trends 2012: Preventing a deeper job crisis. Publication, Geneva: international Labour Office, 2012.…

    • 5106 Words
    • 21 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    The author focuses on demographic trends, work and family issues, health and pension patterns, technology changes, unemployment, globalization, and the plight of low-skilled workers.…

    • 852 Words
    • 4 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    Labour laws is defined as the balance of power among government, employers, workers, and unions. The redrafting of a country’s labour laws typically reflects a shift in the power relations and may carry unfavourable consequences for a former beneficiaries. As the Colliers put it, “Labour law is a highly visible and concrete policy statement around which political battles are fought, won, and lost, and around which political support is attracted, granted, and withheld… labour law thus provides a valuable point of reference for analyzing the larger political context” (Collier and Collier 1979, 971).…

    • 7045 Words
    • 29 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Best Essays

    Health and Safety

    • 4301 Words
    • 18 Pages

    References: Barten, F., Fustukian, S. and De Haan, S. (2009) ‘The Occupational Health Needs of Workers: A New International Approach.’ Social Justice, 23…

    • 4301 Words
    • 18 Pages
    Best Essays
  • Best Essays

    Core Labor Standards

    • 2925 Words
    • 12 Pages

    The International Labour Organization (ILO) has outlined five core labor standards that have been universally accepted, but countries are not obligated to follow through since the ILO…

    • 2925 Words
    • 12 Pages
    Best Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    Child Labor In China

    • 1408 Words
    • 6 Pages

    A complex social and political issue that has enrooted employment history for a long period of time; child labor is evolving into a new phenomenon that is having negative impacts on children all throughout the globe. Children involved with child labor can have several different paths to their occupation which can be determined by factors such as poverty, family’s economic status, history, health, and many others. Their work can have major implications such as social disadvantages, poor health, pitiable physical development, and lack of education. Lack of wages are also implemented into the child’s work life, hardly ever approaching minimum wage. Lack of current and future support such as benefits, retirement funds, or insurance, are attached…

    • 1408 Words
    • 6 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Good Essays

    As a labour problem, calling for improved working conditions, the abolishment of child labour and labour monitoring…

    • 563 Words
    • 3 Pages
    Good Essays
  • Satisfactory Essays

    Luxembourg has one of the most comprehensive healthcare systems in the world. It offers virtually unrestricted access to its population. Luxembourg is also ranked amongst the leading ten countries in the world, in terms of per capita healthcare expenditure. Government-funded free basic healthcare is provided to every citizen. The total health spending, as a percentage of GDP (gross domestic product), was about 7.8% in 2012. The Caisse Nationale de Sant (National Health Fund) collects funds for the 97.0% of the population that, as of 2012, was covered by public health insurance in 2012. However, private health insurance services act as a supplement to state health insurance. Private insurance is mainly for medical expenses outside Luxembourg, as well as dental and optical care, which are not covered by the state health insurance. Pressure on government finances and increasing awareness of health insurance due to rising life expectancy will continue to support the demand for personal accident and health insurance products over the forecast period (20122017).…

    • 1192 Words
    • 5 Pages
    Satisfactory Essays
  • Powerful Essays

    Good and Bad Practices in Microinsurance This paper was commissioned by the “Good and Bad Practices in Microinsurance” project. Managed by the ILO’s Social Finance Programme for the CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance, this project is jointly funded by SIDA, DfID, GTZ and the ILO. The major outputs of this project are: 1. A series of case studies to identify good and bad practices in microinsurance 2. A synthesis document of good and bad practices in microinsurance for practitioners based on an analysis of the case studies. The major lessons from the case studies will also be published in a series of two-page briefing notes for easy access by practitioners. 3. Donor guidelines for funding microinsurance. The CGAP Working Group on Microinsurance The CGAP Microinsurance Working Group includes donors, insurers and other interested parties. The Working Group coordinates donor activities as they pertain to the development and proliferation of insurance services to low-income households in developing countries. The main activities of the working group include: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Developing donor guidelines for supporting microinsurance Document case studies of insurance products and delivery models Commission research on key issues such as the regulatory environment for microinsurance Supporting innovations that will expand the availability of appropriate microinsurance products Publishing a quarterly newsletter on microinsurance Managing the content of the Microinsurance Focus website: www.microfinancegateway.org/section/resourcecenters/microinsurance…

    • 18102 Words
    • 73 Pages
    Powerful Essays
  • Best Essays

    * McIsaac, A. D and Babbel, F. D. (1999) ‘ The World Bank Primer and Reinsurance’, Policy research working paper, No. 1512.…

    • 3279 Words
    • 14 Pages
    Best Essays

Related Topics