Preview

trade theory

Good Essays
Open Document
Open Document
5623 Words
Grammar
Grammar
Plagiarism
Plagiarism
Writing
Writing
Score
Score
trade theory
Ricardian Trade Theory
By Kiminori Matsuyama1
Abstract: Ricardian Trade Theory takes cross-country technology differences as the basis of trade. By abstracting from the roles of factor endowment and factor intensity differences, which are the primary concerns of Factor Proportions
Theory, Ricardian Trade Theory offers a simple and yet powerful framework within which to examine the effects of country sizes, of technology changes and transfers, and of income distributions. Moreover, its simple production structure makes it relatively easy to allow for many goods and many countries, hence capable of generating valuable insights, which are lost in the standard twocountry, two-sector model of international trade.
Ricardian Trade Theory takes cross-country technology differences as the basis of trade. By abstracting from the roles of cross-country factor endowment differences and cross-industry factor intensity differences, which are the primary concerns of Factor Proportions Theory (such as Heckscher-Ohlin and Specific Factor models), Ricardian Trade Theory offers a simple and yet powerful framework within which to address many positive and normative issues of international trade. It is particularly well-equipped to examine the effects of country sizes, of technology changes and transfers, and income distributions. Furthermore, its simple production structure makes it relatively easy to allow for many tradeable goods and many countries, hence capable of generating valuable insights, which are lost in the standard two-country, two-goods model of international trade.
Let us start with the Ricardian model with a continuum of tradeable goods, adopted from
Dornbusch, Fischer, and Samuelson (DFS) (1977). The world consists of two countries, Home and Foreign. There is a continuum of competitive industries, indexed by z ∈ [0,1], each producing a homogenous tradeable good, also indexed by z. There is only one nontradeable factor of production, called



Bibliography: Acemoglu, D., P. Antras, and E. Helpman, 2006, “Contracts and Technology Adoption,” MIT and Harvard Working Paper. Acemoglu, D., and J. Ventura, 2002, “The World Income Distribution,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 659-694. Alvarez, F. and R. E. Lucas Jr., 2004, “General Equilibrium Analysis of the Eaton-Kortum model of international trade,” University of Chicago Working Paper. Becker, G., 1952, “A Note on Multi-Country Trade,” American Economic Review, 42, 558-568. Costinot, A., 2006, “On the Origins of Comparative Advantage,” UCSD Working Paper. Dornbusch, R., S. Fischer and P.A. Samuelson, 1977, "Comparative Advantage, Trade and Payments in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods" American Economic Review, Eaton, J. and S. Kortum, 2002, “Technology, Geography, and Trade,” Econometrica, 70, 17411779. Flam, H. and E. Helpman, 1987, “Vertical Product Differentiation and North-South Trade.” American Economic Review Grossman, G., and E. Helpman, 1995, "Technology and Trade," in Ch. 25, G. Grossman and K. Hicks, J. R., 1953, “An Inaugural Lecture,” Oxford Economic Papers, 5, 117-135. Hummels, D., J. Ishii, and K-M. Yi, 2001, “The Nature and Growth of Vertical Integration in World Trade” Journal of International Economics, 54, 75-96. Itoh, M. and K. Kiyono, 1987, “Welfare Enhancing Export Subsidies,” Journal of Political Economy, 95, 115-137. Jones, R. W. 1979, “Technical Progress and Real Incomes in a Ricardian Trade Model,” ch. 17 in R Krugman, P., 1986, “A “Technology-Gap” Model of International Trade,” in K. Jungenfelt and D. Matsuyama, K., 1996, “Why Are There Rich and Poor Countries?: Symmetry-Breaking in the World Economy,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 10, 419-439. Matsuyama, K., 2000, "A Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Goods under Nonhomothetic Preferences: Demand Complementarities, Income Distribution and North-South Trade," Journal of Political Economy, 108, 1093-1120. Matsuyama, K., 2005, “Credit Market Imperfections and Patterns of International Trade and Capital Flows,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 3, 714-723. Matsuyama, K., 2007a, “Beyond Icebergs: Towards a Theory of Biased Globalization,” Review of Economic Studies, 74, 237-253. Matsuyama, K., 2007b, “Productivity-Based Theory of Manufacturing Employment Declines: A Global Perspective.” http://www.faculty.econ.northwestern.edu/faculty/matsuyama/. Matsuyama, K., 2007c, “Uniform versus Non-uniform Globalization.” http://www.faculty.econ.northwestern.edu/faculty/matsuyama/. Sanyal, KK., 1983, “Vertical Specialization in a Ricardian Model with a Continuum of Stages of Production,” Economica, 50, 71-78. Stokey, N., 1991, "The Volume and Composition of Trade between Rich and Poor Countries" Review of Economic Studies, 58, 63-80. Wilson, C. A., 1980, “On the General Structure of Ricardian Models with a Continuum of Goods," Econometrica, 48, 1675-1702. Yanagawa, N., 1996, "Economic Development in a Ricardian World with Many Countries," Journal of Development Economics, 49, 271-288.

You May Also Find These Documents Helpful